Categories
Courses Curriculum Harvard

Harvard. Expansion of Economics Course Offerings. 1883.

_______________________

The tripling of regular economics course offerings at Harvard in the early 1880’s attracted medium (they only had newspapers then, so I suppose the singular form is appropriate) attention as seen in the following story from the New York Evening Post (October 11, 1883) that was picked up by the Chicago Tribune (October 15, 1883).  The expansion in course offerings in political economy was announced in the Harvard Crimson on May 24, 1883.

Here are links to five earlier Harvard-related posts from this period at Economics in the Rear-View Mirror:

1874-77.
Three Economics Courses. Texts and exams
Courses in Political Economy

1881.
Economics. Two Course Reviews

1886.
Account of Graduate Department

1888-89.
Political Economy Courses

_______________________

POLITICAL ECONOMY AT HARVARD [1883].

Sketch of the Reorganized Department – Seven Courses of Study – Their Scope and Aim.
[Correspondence of the Evening Post.]

Cambridge, Mass., October 5. – The Department of Political Economy in Harvard College has undergone an enlargement and organization this year which marks a growing interest in the subject on the part of the students and a readiness on the part of the authorities to give encouragement and increased opportunity for its pursuit. For some years political economy was taught practically in two courses, an introductory one, which developed the principles of the English school, Mill being the author used, and an advanced course, which took up Cairnes’ Leading Principles of Political Economy, and discussed also banking and finance. Some years there were two introductory courses instead of one, but in that case they were alternative, and not supplementary. Last year the field treated was broadened by the addition of course, given by Dr. Laughlin, on the economic effects of land tenures in England, Ireland, France, Germany, and Russia; and this year the return of Professor Dunbar from his vacation in Europe, and the retention of both Dr. Laughlin, now assistant professor, and Mr. Taussig, has resulted in the expansion of the whole treatment into seven courses of study. A brief account of the scope and character of these courses is as follows:

First, there is one course intended to give familiarity with the leading principles of the science. Mill’s book is here used as a basis, but there are also lectures on banking and the critical review of the public finance of the United States, chiefly during and since the last war. The course aims to give that general knowledge which every educated man ought to have. For those, however, wish to attain a thorough mastery of the principles of economics, one course is not deemed sufficient. Consequently course 2 – a history of economic theory and a critical examination of leading writers – is given by Professor Dunbar. He will take up all the principal writers in England, France, Germany, and Italy, and will review other recent literature, including the work of Henry George. He intends us to develop a grasp upon the fundamental principles that will enable the student to do practical work of real value.

The other five subjects are designed to turn the attention of students to the historical and practical side, affording training in the use of books and sources, the collection of statistics, and the investigation of such public questions as constantly arise from year to year. They are as follows:

Course 3. Discussion of Practical Economic Questions. – The work will here be done in discussion of live questions of the day, and in written monographs upon subjects which most concern the economic interests of the United States, for example: The navigation laws and American shipping; bimetallism; reciprocity with Canada; advantages of Government issues of notes compared with those of national banks.

Course 4. Economic History of Europe and America since the Seven Years’ War. This is in the form of lectures by Professor Dunbar, and will trace the economic effects of the great events in the history of the last 125 years.

Course 5. Economic Effects of Land Tenures in England, Ireland, France, and Germany; is the course which was introduced by Professor Laughlin last year, and which he gives again; the work is mostly in the form of written theses.

Course 6. History of Tariff Legislation in the United States, by Mr. Taussig; is a study of the tariff laws which the country has tried, and of the reasons for their passage or repeal. The scope of the course is best seen in the following useful syllabus:

I. 1789-1816: Tariff system adopted after the formation of the Constitution; Hamilton’s report; the state of the protective controversy before 1816; the beginnings of manufacturing industry.
II. 1816-1840: The American System; Henry Clay; the tariffs of 1824, 1828, 1832; the Compromise Tariff of 1833; the growth of manufactures; the economic effects of protection.
III. 1840-1860: The political tariffs of 1842 (protectionist); 1846 (free trade); the industrial progress of the country from 1846 to 1860.
IV. 1860-1883: The Civil War; the development of the existing tariff system; the revenue act of 1864; the tax-reducing acts of later years; the tariff revision of 1883.

Course 7. Comparison of the Financial Systems of France, England, Germany, and the United States; is conducted by Professor Dunbar. He will compare the systems adopted by these nations to provide themselves with revenues, and will direct the study to the economic principles underlying public finance and closely connected with the science of government.

 

Source: New York Evening Post, October 11, 1883, p. 2. Scan of the page at Historical Newspapers From The United States and Canada, Archives of the New York Evening Post Newspaper, pdf-page 0360.

Image Source: The Miriam and Ira D. Wallach Division of Art, Prints and Photographs: Photography Collection, The New York Public Library. “Sever Hall, Harvard Univ., Cambridge, Mass.” The New York Public Library Digital Collections. 1898 – 1931.

 

 

 

 

 

Categories
Bibliography Curriculum Toronto

Toronto. Economics curriculum. 1932-33

____________________________

In preparing the previous post that transcribed the honours examination for money, credit and prices at the University of Toronto in 1933, I discovered that the annual calendar of the University provided an excellent overview of the economics curriculum that included short course descriptions along with brief reference bibliographies for each of the courses. This falls short of having detailed course syllabi with precise reading assignments and lecture notes but it does have the virtue of wall-to-wall coverage of the economics curriculum at the time.

____________________________

 

Economics course requirements in the Honour Course for Political Science and Economics 1932-33

 

FIRST YEAR

Hours

Economics 1a. A General Sketch of Economic History.

3

Economics 1h. An Introduction to Economics.

2

 

SECOND YEAR

Hours

Economics 2e. Principles of Economics.

3

Economics 2f. Structure of Modern Industry.

3

Economics 2g. Statistics.

3

 

THIRD YEAR

Hours

Economics 3d. Labour Problems.

3

Economics 3e. Money, Credit and Prices.

3

Economics 3g. Taxation and public finance.

3

Economics 3h. Banking.

1

 

FOURTH YEAR

Hours

Economics 4e. Advanced Economic Theory.

3

Economics 4f. Economic History of Canada and the United States.

3

Choose one* of:

Economics 4h. Corporation Finance.

2

Economics 4i. International Financial and Trade Policies.

3

Economics 4j. The Diagnosis of Business Conditions.

2

Economics 4k. Transportation.

3

Economics 4l. Advanced Economic Geography.

2

Economics 4m. Economics of Mineral Products.

2

Economics 4n. Rural Economics.

2

Economics 4o. Demography

2

*Each student will also do special work in one of the honour subjects. This special work will count for purposes of standing as an additional subject in the course. The choice of the subject in which such special work is to be done must be made not later than the last day of October; and the written work involved must be concluded by the student not later than the last day of the following February.

____________________________

 

POLITICAL SCIENCE AND
COMMERCE AND FINANCE

E. J. Urwick, M.A. Professor of Economics
W. T. Jackman, M.A. Professor of Transportation
G. E. Jackson, B.A. Professor and Supervisor of Studies for the course in Commerce and Finance
W. S. Ferguson, C.A. Professor of Accounting (part-time)
H. A. Innis, M.A., Ph.D. Associate Professor
H. R. Kemp, M.A. Associate Professor
A. Brady, M.A., Ph.D. Associate Professor
V. W. Bladen, M.A. Assistant Professor
W. M. Drummond, M.A. Assistant Professor
L. T. Morgan, M.A., Ph.D. Assistant Professor
F. R. Crocombe, M.A., C.A. Assistant Professor of Accounting
C. A. Ashley, B.Com., A. C.A. Assistant Professor of Accounting
J. G. Perold, M.A., B.D. Lecturer
J. F. Parkinson, B.Com. Lecturer
Miss I. M. Biss, M.A. Lecturer
D. C. MacGregor, B.A. Lecturer
A. F. W. Plumptre, B.A. Lecturer
O. P. N. Van der Sprenkel, B.Sc. Lecturer
A. E. Grauer, B.A., Ph. D. Lecturer
A. J. Glazebrook Special Lecturer in Banking and Finance
D, W. Buchanan, B.A. Assistant
J. A. Trites, B.A. Assistant

 

ECONOMICS
Pass Courses

1a. A General Sketch of Economic History. For reference: Ashley, Economic Organization of England; Cheyney, Industrial and Social History of England; Knowles, Industrial and Commercial Revolutions. Three hours a week.

1b. The same as 2a.

1c. Organization of industry. A description of modern Industrial society, with emphasis on large-scale business enterprise, labour organization, and unemployment. For reference: Robertson, Control of Industry; The Engineers’ Report on Waste in Industry; Cole, An Introduction to Trade Unionism; Annual Report of the Department of Labour (Ottawa) on Labour Organization in Canada. National Bureau of Economic Research, Recent Economic Changes; Liberal Committee of Enquiry, Britain’s Industrial Future. Two hours a week.

1d. Social Science. Historical outline of the extension of man’s power over nature, and the development of social forms. For reference: Marett, Anthropology; Mueller-Lyer, History of Social Development; Goldenweiser, Early Civilization; Davis et al, Introduction to Sociology; MacIver, Community. One and a half hours a week.

1e. The Industrial Revolution. One hour a week.

 

2a. Introduction to the Study of Economics. The elements of economic theory with some account of contemporary economic institutions. For reference: Ely, Outlines of Economics; Atkins et al, Economic Behaviour, An Institutional Approach; Fairchild and Compton, Economic Problems; Clay, Economics for the General Reader; Robertson, Money; Henderson, Supply and Demand; Carver, The Distribution of Wealth; Slichter, Modern Economic Society. Two hours a week.

2b. Economic Theory. For reference: Adam Smith, Wealth of Nations; Malthus, Essay on Population; Ricardo, Political Economy; Mill, Principles of Political Economy; Cannan, Theories of Production and Distribution; Marx and Engels, The Communist Manifesto; Gide and Rist, History of Economic Doctrines; Davenport, Value and Distribution; Levinsky, The Founders of Political Economy; Carr-Saunders, Population; Spargo, Socialism; Bastable, Public Finance; Stamp, Principles of Taxation; Seligman, Essays in Taxation. Three hours a week.

2c. Commerce of Nations. A course dealing with the characteristics of foreign trade and with the theories of international trade and prices: currency systems, money, and banking in relation to price fluctuations, the balance of international payments, the foreign exchanges, capital movements; statistical aspects of foreign trade; the relations of the state to foreign trade, commercial policies and the tariff, etc.; the organization of foreign trade, the functions of produce exchanges, financial institutions, transportation agencies. Foreign trade trends and problems of the leading countries. For reference: Taussig, International Trade, Some Aspects of the Tariff Question; Marshall, Money, Credit and Commerce; Bastable, Commerce of Nations, Theory of International Trade; Todd, The Mechanism of Exchange; Viner, Canada’s Balance of International Payments; Laureys, Foreign Trade of Canada; Kirkaldy and Evans, The History and Economics of Transport, etc. Two hours a week.

2d. The Industrial Revolution. For students in English and History, and Philosophy (English or History Option), etc. For reference: Ashley, Economic Organization of England; Fay, Great Britain from Adam Smith to the Present Day; Knowles, Industrial and Commercial Revolutions in Great Britain during the Nineteenth Century; other works dealing with the more important trends in modern industry. One hour a week.

 

3a. The same as 2a.

3b. The same as 2b.

3c. The same as 2c.

 

4a. Economic History. The Economic History of Great Britain with some reference to the economic development of the Dominions. For reference: Ashley, The Economic Organization of England; Knowles and Knowles, The Economic Development of the British Overseas Empire; Cheyney, Industrial and Social History of England; Fay, Great Britain from Adam Smith to the Present Day; Knight, Barnes and Flugel, Economic History of Europe; Knowles, Industrial and Commercial Revolutions in Great Britain during the seventeenth century. Three hours a week.

4b, Finance of Government. Commencing with a theoretical analysis of the dispersion of taxation and other burdens among the agents of production, followed by a study of the canons of taxation, the growth of modern progressive taxation, various tax systems, the conflict of federal, provincial and local tax jurisdictions, non-fiscal aspects of taxation, and the history and significance of public borrowing and expenditure in modern capitalism. For reference: same as 3g. Two hours a week.

4c. Finance of Industry and Commerce. Money and credit; foreign trade; corporation finance. For reference: Day, Money and Banking System of U.S.; Beckhart, Canadian Banking System; Withers, War and Lombard Street; Stocks and Shares; Business of Finance; Royal Bank, Financing Foreign Trade; Dominion and Ontario Companies’ Acts. Two hours a week.

4d. Elements of Statistics. An elementary course in statistical methods and their application to economic problems. Laboratory work will be required. For reference: Elderton, Primer of Statistics; Thurstone, Fundamentals of Statistics; Secrist, Introduction to Statistical Methods; Canada Year Book; Labour Gazette and other publications. Three hours a week.

 

Honour Courses

1f. Economic History. Economic History with special reference to British development from 1760 onwards, based on Ashley, Economic Organization of England; Mantoux, Industrial Revolution in the Eighteenth Century; Knight, Barnes and Flugel, Economic History of Europe; Knowles, Industrial and Commercial Revolutions. For references: Fay, Great Britain from Adam Smith to the Present Day, Life and Labour in the Nineteenth Century; Hammond, Lord Shaftesbury, The Town Labourer; Buxton, Finance and Politics; Rees, Fiscal and Financial History of England, 1815-1918; Prothero, English Farming, Past and Present; Jackman, Transportation in Modern England; Dicey, Law and Opinion in England. Three hours a week.

1g. Geography. A general introduction to economic geography; temperature, wind systems, and rainfall; influences on economic enterprise and on migration; relation of the Old World to the New; seaports and trade routes; food supplies and population. For reference: Huntington and Gushing, Principles of Human Geography; Huntington and Carlson, Environmental Basis of Social Geography; Russell Smith, North America; Lyde, The Continent of Europe; Bartholomew and Lyde, The Oxford Economic Atlas and Supplement (1914); Corrado Gini and others, Population; The Canada Year Book; and other publications of Government Departments. Two hours a week.

1h. An Introduction to Economics. For students in Modern History, Political Science and Economics, and Law. A survey of the forces governing the production and consumption of wealth and of the character and development of the existing economic system. For reference: Cannan, Wealth; Thorp, Economic Institutions; Clay, Economics for the General Reader; Robertson, Control of Industry; Mueller-Lyer, The History of Social Development. Two hours a week.

 

2e. Principles of Economics. An explanation of economic theory, based chiefly upon Marshall, Principles of Economics and Cassel, Theory of Social Economy. For reference: Carver, Distribution of Wealth; Smart, Distribution of Income; Taussig, Principles of Economics; Withers, The Meaning of Money; Wright, Population. Three hours a week.

2f. Structure of Modern Industry. A description of some important characteristics of modern industry, as a basis for understanding the pure theory of economics and discovering some of its limitations. For reference: Marshall, Industry and Trade; Laidler, Concentration in American Industry; Clark, Economics of Overhead Costs, and Social Control of Business; Holmes, Economics of Farm Organization and Management; Taylor, Scientific Management; Bogert and Landon, Modern Industry; Reports of special Government investigators under the Combines Investigation Act; Sittings, Canadian Advisory Board on Tariff and Taxation; Wilmore, Industrial Britain; Kieger and May, The Public Control of Business; Watkins, Industrial Combinations and Public Policy; Jones, Trust Problems in the United States; Domeratzky, International Cartels; Robertson, Control of Industry; Patton, Co-operative Marketing of Grain in Western Canada; Canada Year Book, etc. Three hours a week.

2g. Statistics. General introduction to the use of statistics; methods of collection, tabulation, graphic presentation, analysis, and interpretation, and application to the study of business cycles, population, and other economic problems. Survey of some of the principal sources of statistical information. A considerable part of the course will be devoted to laboratory work. For reference: Mills, Statistical Methods; Secrist, An Introduction to Statistical Methods; Crum and Patton, Economic Statistics; Chaddock, Principles and Methods of Statistics; Yule, Introduction to the Theory of Statistics; Bowley, Introductory Manual of Statistics, and Elements of Statistics; Fisher, Making of Index Numbers; Mitchell, Index Numbers of Wholesale Prices in the United States and Foreign Countries (Bulletin 284 of U.S. Bureau of Labour Statistics); Labour Gazette (Ottawa); Canada Year Book, Census Reports (Canada, Great Britain, U.S.A.), publications of the Royal Statistical Society and of the American Statistical Association, and other publications to be indicated from time to time. Three hours a week.

 

3d. Labour Problems. A course dealing with the problems and disabilities of labouring people such as unemployment, industrial accident and disease, overstrain, monotony, and low wages and standards of living; with workingmen’s efforts to solve these problems through trade unionism, consumers’ co-operation, political action, and social revolutionary programmes; with employers’ methods of meeting the problems of labour; and with intervention by the state in the interests of labour through protective legislation. For reference: Douglas, Hitchcock and Atkins, The Worker in Modern Economic Society; Blum, Labour Economics; Douglas, The Problem of Unemployment; Hamilton and May, The Control of Wages; Webb, Industrial Democracy; Stewart, Canadian Labour Laws and the Treaty; Canadian Department of Labour, The Labour Gazette (monthly) and Annual Reports on Labour Organization in Canada. Three hours a week.

3e. Money, Credit and Prices. A course dealing with monetary theory and related subjects, including the discussion of the rôle of money in economic theory; bimetallism; the gold standard; the gold exchange standard; the relation between money, credit, production and prices; the business cycle; central banks and the control of credit; stabilization of business; the foreign exchanges; the rôle of money in the theory of international trade; money and foreign exchange; problems in various countries, including reparations. For reference: Cassel, Theory of Social Economy, Vol.II, and Money and Foreign Exchange after 1914; Fisher, The Purchasing Power of Money; Keynes, A Treatise on Money; Marshall, Money Credit and Commerce; Edie, Money, Bank Credit and Prices; Willis and Beckhart, Foreign Banking Systems; Burgess, Interpretations of the Federal Reserve Bank; Mitchell, Business Cycles, the Problem, and its Setting; Snyder, Business Cycles and Business Measurements; Hobson, Rationalization and Unemployment; Gregory, Foreign Exchange; Taussig, International Trade; Angell, International Prices; The Young Plan; Reports of Agent General for Reparations; Reports of League of Nations Gold Delegation; The Macmillan Report, 1931; Current Financial Literature. Three hours a week.

3f. The same as 2g.

3g. Part I. The Distribution of Taxation. Based upon an extension, application and criticism of the theory of the distribution of wealth. For reference: Smith and Ricardo on taxation; Seligman, Incidence of Taxation, Essays in Taxation; Report of the Committee on National Debt and Taxation, G. B. 1927; J. A. Hobson, The Industrial System, Taxation in the New State; Pigou, Public Finance; H. G. Brown, Economics of Taxation; Silverman, Taxation — Its Incidence and Effects.
Part II. Principles of Public Finance. Economic functions of the state, the canons of taxation, revenue systems of modern states, national and local taxation, public debts, expenditure, the public domain. For reference: Bastable, Public Finance; Lutz, Public Finance; Shirras, Science of Public Finance; Bullock, Readings in Public Finance. In addition, monographs, periodicals and statistical records will be found essential. For examination and essay purposes, the two parts of this course will be considered as one. Three hours a week.

3h. Banking. A special course on the theory and practice of banking operations. One hour a week.

3i. Business Administration. The same as 4g.

3j. Economic Basis of Social Life. A sketch of modern economic organization with particular reference to the way in which economic factors condition social life. The course includes description of the production process, the business system, the price system, group conflicts over income and status, and standards of living; appraisal of the functioning of the economic order; and brief inquiry into the problem of control. For reference: Lynd, Middletown; Soule, The Useful Art of Economics; Keezer, Cutler and Garfield, Problem Economics; Clay, Economics for the General Reader; Thorp, Economic Institutions; Robertson, The Control of Industry.

 

4e. Advanced Economic Theory. A course dealing with the evolution of economic thought through the principal schools from Adam Smith to the present, and giving special attention to the criticism of current theories of value, interest, rent and wages. For reference: Adam Smith, Wealth of Nations; Malthus, Essay on Population; Ricardo, Principles of Political Economy; List, National System of Political Economy; Marx, Capital; Böhm-Bawerk, The Positive Theory of Capital; J. B. Clark, Distribution of Wealth; Marshall, Principles of Economics; Pigou, Economics of Welfare; Cassel, Theory of Social Economy; Cannan, Review of Economic Theory, and Theories of Production and Distribution; Dalton, Inequalities of Incomes. Three hours a week.

4f. Economic History of Canada and the United States. The significance of economic factors in the growth of western civilization on the North American continent with special reference to Canada. For reference: Select Documents in Canadian Economic History, Vols. I, II, especially selected; bibliography, Vol. I, pp. 579-581, and The Fur Trade in Canada; An Introduction to Canadian Economic History; A History of the Canadian Pacific Railway (Toronto, 1923); Cambridge History of the British Empire (Vol. on Canada). L. C. A. Knowles and C. M. Knowles, Economic Development of the British Overseas Empire, Vol. II, bibliography. Contributions to Canadian Economics; Proceedings of the Canadian Political Science Association; economic history sections, Canada and its Provinces; C. R. Fay, The Corn Laws and Social England. Three hours a week.

4g. Business Administration. In each term throughout the session a course of special lectures on a selected field of Canadian finance or industry will be given by lecturers practically conversant with its problems. One hour a week.

4h. Corporation Finance. Economic service of corporations; capitalization; detailed study of stocks and bonds; financing of extensions and improvements; management of incomes and reserves; dividend policy; insolvency; receiverships; reorganizations. For reference: Poor’s Financial Service is unexcelled; Lincoln, Applied Business Finance, and Problems in Business Finance; Nelson, Readings in Corporation Finance; Mead, Corporation Finance; Willis and Bogen, Investment Banking; Sloan, Corporation Profits; Gerstenberg, Materials of Corporation Finance; Dewing, Corporation Finance. Two hours a week.

4i. International Financial and Trade Policies. The chief characteristics of world economic relationships in the post-war setting. Economic causes of international friction in the light of recent history. Economic consequences of the Peace Treaties; the Reparations Problem; Inter-Allied debts. Monetary reconstruction; currency and banking experiments; the Gold Standard to-day; the silver situation. Commercial policies of leading countries; the Tariff and economic nationalism; international collaboration and the economic section of the League of Nations. World capital movements; U.S.A. as a creditor nation; financial co-operation; the Young Plan and the Bank for International Settlements. Currency and Trade problems of the British Empire. For reference: Keynes, Economic Consequences of the Peace, Revision of the Treaty; Bergman, History of Reparations; Moulton, The Reparation Plan, Germany’s Capacity to Pay; Culbertson, Commercial Policy in war time and after; Dawes’ Report; The Young Plan; Einzig, The Bank for International Settlements; Rogers, The Process of Inflation in France; Reports and Documents of the Gold Delegation Committee of the League of Nations; Williams, Economic Foreign Policy of the United States, etc. Three hours a week.

4j. The Diagnosis of Business Conditions. A review of the functions of the consulting economist, and of the materials available to him; analysis and interpretation of time series, and consideration of underlying forces affecting the world’s credit. The course is conducted with special reference to the period from 1925 to the present. For reference: National Bureau of Economic Research, Recent Economic Changes; Persons and others, The Problem of Business Forecasting; Carl Snyder, Business Cycles and Business Measurements; Snider, Business Statistics; Persons, Forecasting Business Cycles; The MacMillan Report; League of Nations Report on The Course and Phases of the World Economic Depression; Canada Year Book; and Monthly Review of Business Statistics. Two hours a week.

4k. Transportation. Railway finance and rates; principles of rate making as established by the railways, the regulative tribunals and the courts; railway policy in Canada and the other chief countries; railway rate structures; organization of ocean commerce; ocean freight rates; shipping conferences and their results; relations of ocean and land transportation interests; inland water transportation; highway transportation. For reference: Poor’s Financial Service; Jackman, Economics of Transportation; Daggett, Principles of Inland Transportation; Vanderblue and Burgess, Railroads; Rates-Service- Management; Jones, Principles of Railway Transportation; Kidd, A New Era for British Railways; Johnson and Huebner, Principles of Ocean Transportation. Three hours a week.

4l. Advanced Economic Geography. A seminar course dealing with probable changes in the near future in the direction and character of the world’s trade. Bowman, The New World (New York, 1928); J. Brunhes, Human Geography; Vidal de la Blache, Principles of Human Geography; J. M. Clark, Economics of Overhead Costs; H. Laureys, Foreign Trade of Canada (bibliography); W. J. Donald, Canadian Iron and Steel Industry; J. Viner, Canada’s Balance of International Indebtedness; W. W. Swanson and P. C. Armstrong, Wheat; E. S. Moore, Mineral Resources of Canada; W. T. Jackman, Economics of Transportation; H. A. Innis, Fur Trade of Canada; J. A. Todd, World’s Cotton Crops; C. Jones. Commerce of South America; Commission of Conservation, reports; Report of the Royal Commission on Pulpwood, 1924; Report of the Royal Commission on Maritime Fisheries, 1928; National Problems of Canada, McGill University Studies; R. Tanghe, Geographie Humaine de Montreal (Montreal, 1928), and other books to be referred to throughout the course. Two hours a week.

4m. Economics of Mineral Products. A study of mineral resources and the rôle played by them in commerce and industry, with special reference to the minerals of Canada and their use in Canadian industry. (Course 22, Department of Geology, page 171). For reference: Leith, Economic Aspects of Geology; Spurr, Political and Commercial Geology; Moore, Mineral Resources of Canada; McGraw-Hill, Mineral Industry; Moore, Coal; Tarr, Introductory Economic Geology. Two hours a week.

4n. Rural Economics. A course designed to study, first, the nature and extent of the relationship existing between satisfactory economic conditions in agriculture and satisfactory conditions in all other industrial and commercial pursuits and in the life of the community; second, the possibilities of and limitations to applying economic principles in the internal and external organization and operations of the agricultural industry. For reference: Black, Production Economics and Agricultural Reform in the United States; Holmes, Economics of Farm Organization and Management; Garratt, Organization of Farming; McMillan, Too Many Farmers; Bennet, Farm Costs; Warren and Pierson, Interrelationships of Supply, Demand and Price; Stokdyk and West, The Farm Board; Hedden, How Great Cities are Fed; MacIntosh, Agricultural Co-operation in Western Canada; Canadian and United States University and Government Publications in the field of agricultural economics. Two hours a week.

4o. Demography. The statistical study of population, including vital statistics, census procedure, and a more advanced study of the problems arising out of these materials, with special reference to Canada. Two hours a week.

4p. Industry and Human Welfare. Work and working conditions in industry and agriculture and reactions upon the lives of the workers. The wage system and the importance of the job to the individual. The problems of unemployment, industrial accident and disease, woman and child labour, overstrain and superannuation, monotony, and industrial and social status of the workers. Labour on the farm. Group efforts to improve conditions, as by trade unionism, producers’ and consumers’ co-operation, and political action. Governmental protection of standards of work and life. For reference: Catlin, The Labour Problem; Douglas, The Problem of Unemployment; Davison, The Unemployed; Hamilton and May, The Control of Wages; Cole, A Short History of the British Working Class Movement; Tawney, Acquisitive Society; Laidler, History of Socialism.

4g. Social History. An analysis of the reactions of economic and cultural changes upon social life and structure, with special reference to the history of Europe since 1349. The course includes an account of the genesis of present social conditions and social difficulties, and a detailed study of remedial and preventive measures, both public and private, and of the principles underlying these. Books: Vinogradoff, The Manor; Nicholls and MacKay, History of the English Poor Laws; Ribton Turner, History of Vagrancy; Penty, A Guildsman’s Interpretation of History; Tawney, Religion and the Rise of Capitalism; Lecky, England in the 18th Century; Eden, The State of the Poor; Cobbett, Rural Rides; Hayes, Political and Social History of Modern Europe; Reports of the Poor Law Commissioners, 1834 and 1909; Webb, History of Trade Unionism; Kirkman Gray, History of Philanthropy; Cooke Taylor, The Factory System; Cole, History of the Working Class Movement; Traill, Social England, Vols. V and VI; Hammond, The Agricultural Labourer, and the Town Labourer; Cole, Life of Owen; Hammond, Life of Shaftesbury.

 

Source: University of Toronto Calendar, Faculty of Arts 1932-1933. University of Toronto Press, 1932. Pp. 108-116, 206-208.

Image Source: The Library, University of Toronto (September 1939). Archives and Record Management, University of Toronto.

 

 

Categories
Courses Exam Questions Toronto

Toronto. Honors Exam. Money, Credit and Prices. 1933

_______________________________

The honors examination questions for Money, Credit and Prices from the University of Toronto transcribed below were filed away by A. G. Hart in a folder marked “Chi[cago] Qualifying”, perhaps not an ideal resting place for this particular archival artifact. At least now these exam questions are discoverable through a standard internet search and provide researchers going to the University of Toronto archives a tip should they search for economics course materials there.

_______________________________

Course descriptions

3e. Money, Credit and Prices. A course dealing with monetary theory and related subjects, including the discussion of the role of money in economic theory; bimetallism; the gold standard; the gold exchange standard; the relation between money, credit, production and prices; the business cycle; central banks and the control of credit; stabilization of business; the foreign exchanges; the role of money in the theory of international trade; money and foreign exchange; problems in various countries, including reparations. For reference: Cassel, Theory of Social Economy, Vol. II, and Money and Foreign Exchange after 1914; Fisher, The Purchasing Power of Money; Keynes, A Treatise on Money; Marshall, Money, Credit and Commerce; Edie, Money, Bank Credit and Prices; Willis and Beckhart, Foreign Banking Systems; Burgess, Interpretations of the Federal Reserve Bank; Mitchell, Business Cycles, the Problem, and its Setting; Snyder, Business Cycles and Business Measurements; Hobson, Rationalization and Unemployment; Gregory, Foreign Exchange; Taussig, International Trade; Angell, International Prices; The Young Plan; Reports of Agent General for Reparations; Reports of League of Nations Gold Delegation; The Macmillan Report, 1931; Current Financial Literature. Three hours a week.

3h. Banking. A special course on the theory and practice of banking operations. One hour a week.

 

Source: University of Toronto Calendar, Faculty of Arts 1932-33. University of Toronto Press, pp. 112-113.

Image Source: Detail from photo of A. F. Wynne Plumptre (1972) from the University of Toronto Archives Image Bank.

_______________________________

Card paper clipped to examination copy

I thought you might find this of interest.
A. F. Wynne Plumptre [B.A., Lecturer]
Kings College, Cambridge
Toronto, Canada

_______________________________

 

UNIVERSITY OF TORONTO
FACULTY OF ARTS

ANNUAL EXAMINATIONS, 1933

THIRD YEAR—HONOUR

ECONOMICS 3e, 3h
MONEY, CREDIT AND PRICES

Examiners—The Staff in Economics

 

(Question ONE must be answered by all candidates, and THREE or FOUR other questions.)

  1. What do you mean by “inflation”? Under what circumstances, if any, is it desirable?
  2. The following figures appear in the monthly returns of the combined Canadian Chartered Banks:

(in millions of dollars)

Sept. 1929. Sept. 1932.
Current Commercial loans

1,404

1,003

Total Securities held

487

704

Demand Deposits

759

481

Notice Deposits

1,471

1,359

Bank Notes in circulation

197

132

Finance Act borrowings

79

23

Sketch the probable causes of these movements.

  1. It is said, often in criticism of French financial methods, that the power of finance is used in that country to further political ends. In England, on the other hand, efforts have usually been made to keep “politics” dissociated from “finance”; i.e., to keep politicians from dictating the country’s monetary and financial policies. How far, in your opinion, can or should the two be kept separate in Canada or any other country?
  2. “The establishment of the federal reserve bank system…is actually the reason why they have had the recent trouble in the United States banks.” (Sir John Aird, quoted in the Toronto Daily Star, March 22nd, 1933.) How far do you agree with this statement?
  3. In maintaining the gold standard, “world wide international co-operation becomes all but essential just at the moment when the particular local manifestations of the universal trouble occupy the whole attention of the Government in each country and make international action specially difficult.” (Sir Basil Blackett.) Is this a fair summary of the causes of the breakdown of the international gold standard? If so, does it necessarily follow that the restoration and subsequent maintenance of the gold standard is impracticable?
  4. Give an outline of what is meant by any two of the following policies:

Bimetallism,
Remonetization of silver,
Revaluation of gold,
Reduction of central bank reserve ratios.

  1. Outline very briefly the theory of “comparative costs” in international trade. How far do you think it is desirable that members of the newly appointed Canadian tariff board should be familiar with the principles of this theory?
  2. Do you believe that monetary policy is, or might be, a major factor in determining the level of prices and prosperity in either Canada or England or some other country? (Candidates should answer this question with respect to one country only.)
  3. “Booms and slumps are simply the expression of the results of an oscillation of the rate of interest about its equilibrium position.” (J. M. Keynes.) How far do you agree?
  4. Suppose that, at the forthcoming World Economic Conference, it were generally agreed that international exchange rates should be stabilized immediately. What factors would you then take into consideration in estimating at what rate the Canadian dollar should be stabilized? How far would the theory of “purchasing power parity” assist you?
  5. It appears to be customary for monetary theorists to make use of equations in explaining their theories. Why do you think they have used this method? Do you think that such an equation is likely to clarify or becloud the theory to which it refers?

 

Source: Columbia University Archives. Albert Gailord Hart Papers, Box 60, Folder “Exams: Chi[ago] Qualifying”

 

Categories
Chicago Cornell Economists

Chicago. Labor Economics Professor Robert Franklin Hoxie. Suicide, 1916

__________________________

While working on a list of University of Chicago Ph.D.’s in economics, I came across the press report (transcribed below) of the tragic death of an early pioneer in the field of labor economics (then known as “labor problems”) at the University of Chicago.

What might have been, had this scholar’s life not ended so early?

__________________________

Hoxie, Robert Franklin in the Columbia Encyclopedia (6th ed.)

Charles Robert McCann, Jr. and Vibha Kapuria-Foreman. “Robert Franklin Hoxie: The Contributions of a Neglected Chicago Economist” in Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology 34(B), September 2016: 210-304.

__________________________

Robert Franklin Hoxie: Life and Career

 

1868, April 29. Born in Edmeston, New York.
1893.
Ph.B., University of Chicago.
1893-6.
 Fellow in Political Economy.
1897-8. Acting Professor of Political Economy, Cornell College, Iowa.
1898-1901. Instructor in Economics, Washington University.
1901-2. Acting Professor of Political Economy and Political Science, Washington and Lee University.
1903. Fellow in Political Economy, University of Chicago.
1905. Ph.D., University of Chicago. An analysis of the concepts of demand and supply in their relation to market price. Published as The Demand and Supply Concepts. An Introduction to the Study of Market Price. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1906.
1903-6. Instructor in Economics, Cornell University.
1906-8. Instructor in Political Economy, University of Chicago.
1908-12. Assistant Professor in Political Economy, University of Chicago.
1915. Scientific Management and Labor. New York: D. Appleton and Company.
1912-16. Associate Professor in Political Economy, University of Chicago.
1914-15. Appointee of United States Commission on Industrial Relations.
1916, June 22. Died [suicide].

1917. Publication of Hoxie’s notes and lectures on trade unionism by Lucie B. Hoxie and Nathan Fine:   Trade Unionism in the United States, with an Introduction by E. H. Downey. New York: D. Appleton and Company.
2006. Publication of “Robert Hoxie’s Introductory Lecture on the Nature of the History of Political Economy [1915]: The History of Economic Thought as the History of Error.” Edited by Luca Fiorito and Warren J. Samuels in  Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology, Vol. 24-C, 49-97.

__________________________

TEACHER SUICIDE
Professor Takes Life While Suffering Mental Collapse

Prof. R. F. Hoxie Takes His Life

University of Chicago Student of Labor Problems Cuts His Throat

Robert Franklin Hoxie, associate professor of political economy in the University of Chicago, committed suicide yesterday.

Prof. Hoxie had been for years the subject of a nervous depression, his associates said yesterday upon learning of his death. He was constantly in charge of a physician.

While worry over the justice of his economic conclusions was not a direct cause of his act, his desire to view labor problems scientifically was regarded as the keynote of his career. He has been charged with bias resulting from labor affiliations and socialistic leanings. He denied this, and seemed overanxious to maintain a position of scientific neutrality in his studies.

He was to have delivered his first lecture of the summer term yesterday. He had asked his physician, Dr. Archibald Church, if he would be permitted to meet his classes. Dr. Church told him he could do so with safety. When it came time to leave his home at 6021 Woodlawn avenue for the university he was unable to go.

Unable to Meet Class.

“I haven’t the power to meet the pupils,” he told Mrs. Hoxie. “I think you had better have a notice to that effect posted on the bulletin board.”

Mrs. Hoxie left the house, and in a few moments had placed on the bulletin board the note saying that Prof. Hoxie would not lecture. She returned home, and upon entering found her husband lying on the floor. He had cut his throat and severed the veins of his wrist. Mrs. Hoxie’s screams brought neighbors.

There was an inquest in the afternoon, at which it was determined that the professor had taken his own life in a fit of insanity.

Praise from Judson.

“He was a very enthusiastic student of his subject,” said President Harry Pratt Judson of the university, “and a very able student of labor conditions. His death is a distinct loss to the university. He had been in ill health for years and it is a tribute to his will power that he forced himself to continue in his work as he did.”

Samuel Gompers, president of the American Federation of Labor, who was in the city yesterday, said Prof. Hoxie had done more toward the study of labor problems than any other man.

Prof. Hoxie left besides his widow a son of 4 and a daughter 2 years old.

He was statistician for the United States commission on industrial relations and was associate editor of the Journal of Political Economy. He was the author of a work on political economy and numerous articles. He had been a member of the faculties of Cornell college, Washington and Lee university, and Cornell university. His most recent work was a study of scientific management.

 

Source: Chicago Tribune, June 23, 1916, p. 1.

Image Source: University of Chicago Photographic Archive, apf1-02878, Special Collections Research Center, University of Chicago Library.

Categories
Bibliography Chicago Germany Harvard

Germany. Articles on German Universities by Edmund J. James, 1880s

This post assembles five articles on German universities published by one of the founders of the American Economic Association, its twelfth president Edmund Janes James who like many of his contemporaries received his training in economics in Germany. It is interesting to see how in the 1880’s “Seminar” was italicized as a foreign word. Visitors to Economics in the Rear-View Mirror with experience in German/Austrian universities should find James’ observations and comparisons interesting as well. Biographical information about James is provided in today’s post as an extra bonus.

Americans studying in Germany, 1878

Biography of Edmund Janes James up to 1896

Publications of Edmund Janes James

“What is a German University” (1881)

“The Lecture versus the Recitation System” (1882)

“German Student Life” (1882)

“Political Economy in German Universities” (1882)

“The Degree of Ph.D. in Germany” (1888)

 

___________________________________

Americans studying in Germany, 1878

The number of American students at German universities during the year 1878 amounted to 94, of whom 35 were at Berlin, 16 at Bonn, 30 at Göttingen. 2 at Breslau, 2 at Greifswald, 4 at Halle, 1 at Kiel, 2 at Marburg, and 2 at Münster. These students were scattered among all the faculties: 8 study theology, 11 law, 25 medicine, 22 philosophy and philology, 25 mathematics and natural sciences, and 8 financial science.

Source: Illinois School Journal, vol. I, no. 3 and 4 (July and August, 1881), p. 43.

 

___________________________________

 

Biography of Edmund Janes James up to 1896

Dr. Edmund J. James, President of the Academy, leaves the University of Pennsylvania for the University of Chicago, February 1, 1896. In the University of Pennsylvania Dr. James was Professor of Public Finance and Administration in the Department of Finance and Economy (Wharton School), and Professor of Political and Social Science in the Graduate Faculty (Department of Philosophy). In the University of Chicago he will be Professor of Public Administration in the Department of Political Science, and Director of the University Extension Department.

Edmund Janes James was born May 21, 1855, at Jacksonville, Morgan County, Ill. He was prepared for college in the High School Department of the Illinois State Normal School, at Normal, Ill., from which he graduated in June, 1873.

He entered college at the Northwestern University at Evanston, Ill., in the autumn of 1873. Having been appointed Recorder on the United States Lake Survey he joined (May 1, 1874) the party of Engineer Terry, engaged on the upper St. Lawrence and the lower part of Lake Ontario. At the end of the season he entered Harvard College, matriculating November 2, 1874.

In July, 1875, he went to Europe to study political economy. He matriculated at the University of Halle, October 16, 1875, and after spending four semesters at that institution—during which time he attended lectures also at Berlin and Leipsic—he graduated from Halle in August, 1877, taking the degrees of M. A. and Ph. D.

On his return home in the autumn of 1877 he was appointed principal of the Public High School, in Evanston, Ill., from January 1, 1878. In June, 1879, he resigned this position to accept the principalship of the High School Department of the Illinois State Normal School at Normal, Ill., beginning work in September of that year. He resigned this position at Christmas time, 1882, in order to continue his studies in Europe, which he pursued during the summer semester of 1883 at various German universities.

On July 3, 1883, he was elected Professor of Public Finance and Administration in the Wharton School of Finance and Economy, University of Pennsylvania, to begin work the following September. Since 1886 he has had practical charge of this department. Under his influence its corps of instructors was largely increased, the subjects of instruction multiplied, and its curriculum extended from two years to four, changes which were followed by a large increase in the number of students. It was owing to his personal efforts that instruction in statistics, journalism, sociology, transportation, municipal government, jurisprudence, and politics was added to the work in history, economics, and finance. During this period the Wharton School of Finance and Economy became not only a successful department for higher commercial education, but also one of the leading centres for the study of economics and politics in the United States.

Shortly after going to the University of Pennsylvania, Professor James was also appointed December 12, 1883, Professor of Political and Social Science in the Graduate Faculty (Department of Philosophy), and from January, 1884, to January, 1888, was Secretary of this Faculty. While Secretary he proposed the regulations which with few changes, have remained the rules governing graduate study in the University until the present. He was also the first instructor of the Faculty to introduce the seminary method of instruction which has become such a marked feature of all advanced work in the University. He was in Europe on leave of absence during the academic year 1888-89.

On April 8, 1891, he was elected President of the American Society for the Extension of University Teaching, an association organized to promote the introduction and development of University Extension methods of instruction throughout the United States. He held this position until September 1, 1895, during which time the work of the society was greatly extended and strengthened. The number of lecture courses rose from 42 in 1890-91 to 126 in 1894-95; while the number in attendance increased from 7400 to 20,000.

While at the University Professor James declined various calls to other institutions either as president or professor. He was offered the presidency of two leading western State universities. He was also offered an Assistant Professorship in Political Economy at Harvard in 1890 and the head Professorship of Political Science at the University of Chicago in 1892. He was appointed delegate from the University of Pennsylvania to the tercentenary celebration of Trinity College, Dublin, in 1892, and to the bicentennial of the University of Halle in 1894.

Professor James is an active member of various societies and associations of a scientific and practical character. He has been a member of the National Educational Association since 1879. He was elected a member of the National Council of Education in 1884 and has delivered addresses before the association on “College Education for Business Men,” “University Extension ” and ” Normal School Education.”

He was chosen a member of the American Philosophical Society, April 18, 1884.

Since September, 1885 he has been a member of the American Association for the Advancement of Science; since 1891 a Fellow of that body. He was Vice-President and Chairman of Section I in 1891, and has read papers at its sessions on “The Share of Labor in Distribution,” “Manual Training in the Public Schools” and “The Farmer and Taxation.”

Since 1885 he has been a member of the American Social Science Association; was Secretary of the Department of Social Economy, 1887-88, and one of the directors of the association for the years 1890-92. He has read papers on “The Bullitt Bill Charter of Philadelphia,” “Schools of Political and Social Science,” “The Single Tax Theory.”

As one of the early members (1883) of the Public Education Association of Philadelphia he delivered addresses before that body on “Financial and Administrative Aspects of Public Education,” “The Need of Reorganization in Our Public School System,” etc., and has been for two years past Chairman of the Executive Committee of that body.

He was one of the founders of the American Economic Association in 1885, and, as Chairman of the Committee on Organization, reported the plan which has proved so successful in practice. He was for some time Vice-President and has been a frequent contributor to its series of publications.

Having been much interested in the movement for the preservation and better management of our forests, he was one of the original members (1886) of the Pennsylvania Forestry Association and of the Council of that body. He delivered addresses before the association on “The Relation of the State to our Forests,” “The Economic Significance of Our Forests,” etc.

He was actively concerned in the organization of the Pennsylvania College Association in 1887, which was subsequently converted into the Association of Colleges and Preparatory Schools in the Middle States and Maryland. He delivered addresses at its sessions on ”The American University,” “University Extension,” and “The American College,” and was for some time treasurer of the association.

He was one of the founders of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, and, at the first meeting for formal organization December 14, 1889, was elected President, an office to which he has since been annually re-elected.

He was one of the first to take part in the recent movement for the improvement of city politics in the United States; was one of the organizers of the Municipal League of Philadelphia (out of which the National Association of Municipal Leagues has grown) and served as its first president from December 1, 1891.

Professor James’ contributions to the literature of the subjects in which he has been interested have been numerous.

With Dr. Charles DeGarmo, President of Swarthmore College, he founded the Illinois School Journal, now the Public School Journal, one of the most influential educational periodicals in the West. As editor of this magazine for two years, 1881-82, he contributed many papers to the current discussion of the time, relating to the pedagogical and administrative aspects of public education.

As editor of the Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science he has for the past five years directed the policy of this periodical. Under his direction it has expanded from a quarterly to a bimonthly with numerous supplements, and has grown steadily and rapidly in scope and influence.

In addition to the work on the above periodicals, Professor James was one of the leading contributors to the “Cyclopaedia of Political Science, Political Economy and United States History,” edited by John J. Lalor, Chicago, 1882-84. (Referred to below as Lalor’s Cyclopaedia.)

Source: The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science. Vol. 7 (January, 1896), pp. 78-86.

___________________________________

For more biographical information after 1896:

Edmund Janes James: Twelfth President of the Economic Association, 1910American Economic Review, Vol. 34, No. 3 (September 1944).

Ernest Minor Patterson. The career of Edmund Janes JamesThe Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, Vol. 301, (September, 1955), pp. 97-100.

 

___________________________________

Publications of Edmund Janes James

James B. Childs. A Bibliography of the Published Writings and Addresses of Edmund Janes James (Library School Seminar, University of Illinois, Second Semester, 1919-20).

 

___________________________________

 

WHAT IS A GERMAN UNIVERSITY?

by Edmund Janes James

Source: Illinois School Journal, vol. I, no. 5 (September, 1881), pp. 1-2.

            A German University is a corporation whose objects are the increase and spread of knowledge. Like all institutions of learning the German University consists of professors and students together with the various directors and officers connected with the corporation. The former are divided into four faculties, according to the various branches in which they respectively give and receive instructions, viz., the Theological, the Medical, the Law and the Philosophical faculty. The first three terms explain themselves— they comprehend about what we in this country include in our Law, Medical and Theological schools. The last mentioned faculty, viz., the Philosophical, gives instruction in all branches not included in the three former. It corresponds, to a certain extent, with our College of Liberal Arts. It teaches, not only Mental, Moral and Speculative Philosophy, but also Ancient and Modern Languages, History, Archaeology, the Physical Sciences, Mathematics, the Fine Arts, Political Economy, Sociology, Diplomacy, etc., including about every branch of human science, and quite a number of arts, such as dancing, fencing, riding, drawing and singing, in all of which branches there are instructors in the ordinary university.

These faculties are all independent of one another and yet all most intimately connected. A student enrolled in one has a perfect right to hear any and all the courses in the other faculties without additional expense. Candidates for graduation in one faculty are often required to take studies in another. As for instance, the Medical students are required in some places to hear a course in Speculative Philosophy, while those in Political Economy are expected to hear courses in International Law and the Constitutional History of Germany. The professors in each faculty, and consequently in the whole university are further divided into three classes, viz., ordinary professors, extraordinary professors and privat docenten. The first mentioned are appointed and paid by the government. Taken together, they either constitute or elect the academical senate—the executive body of the university. The extraordinary professors are nominated by the university senate and confirmed by the government. They are entitled to no pay; but it is almost universally the custom to vote them a small salary,—600 or 1,000 thalers. The privat docenten are appointed by the university authorities. They receive no salary, and depend altogether on their fees in case they have no other means of support. These three terms have been translated into English as full professors, assistant professors, and tutors. But the similarity is not great enough to justify such translation. Our assistant professors are simply assistants. They are expected to take the drudgery off the hands of the professor, to take the classes he doesn’t want, to do the elementary work. And our tutors might be called assistant-assistant professors; for they stand in the same relation to the assistant professor that the latter does to the full professor. The relation of the three mentioned classes to one another in the German institution is, however, radically different. The privat docent is just as independent as the ordinary professor. He has the right to lecture on the same subjects, to appeal to the same class of hearers, in a word to compete in the freest manner for the patronage of the students. His certificate that the student has attended his course of lectures counts for just as much in the eyes of the university authorities as the ordinary professor’s certificate. He is on the same footing as the ordinary professor except that he has no salary from the government. These privat docenten may be considered as candidates for professorships. A young man graduates from the university, and desires to devote himself to a university career. He spends a year or two as the case may be in preparing a course of lectures. He then applies for permission to locate in some university. He posts the announcement of his lecture on the bulletin board, and at the time appointed he begins his lecture. Three or four students drop in to see what the new man is like. If he has something to say and can say it in an attractive and forcible manner, he may count upon a full lecture room. If the ordinary professor in that subject has become fossilized or negligent, he may experience the mortification of seeing his lecture-room deserted, and perhaps be finally compelled to hand over his larger lecture room to the younger man because the latter can draw the larger crowd.

We dwell on this matter of the privat docenthum because it seems to us that it is one of the most important elements in the German system. By it is secured, as a rule, constant exertion on the part of the older professors to furnish something new and solid, and to keep themselves fresh and active, lest the younger men supplant them. It offers further, to those young men who wish to follow a university career, an opportunity to begin their work as soon as they have graduated, and if they have the ability, a chance to succeed from the very first. And thus they retain the very cream of the rising generation for university work.

 

___________________________________

 

THE LECTURE VERSUS THE RECITATION SYSTEM

A COMPARISON BETWEEN THE METHODS OF INSTRUCTION IN GERMAN AND AMERICAN UNIVERSITIES.
by Edmund Janes James

Source: Illinois School Journal, vol. I, no. 11 (March, 1882), pp. 13-14.

            In considering the merits of any system of instruction, we ought to have regard to its relations toward both classes of individuals most affected by it, viz., the pupils and the teachers, the students and the professors. We ought to adopt that system which, on the whole, secures the best results for both parties. The catechetical, or recitation system has too exclusive reference to the pupils; the lecture system as practiced in many places, is too exclusively on the side of the teachers. A college professor is an entirely different person in Germany, from what he is here. The Germans make a world-wide difference between the Professor and the Lehrer, or instructor. That difference disappears in our economy. Our professor, as far as we use the word in a technical sense, is one who teaches college boys—the kind of work is exactly the same as the public school teacher’s—the only difference is that he has different subjects, though that isn’t true to the same extent now as formerly. We confine our teachers to the mere routine work of putting into the minds of their students a certain number of text-books. We overload them with work so that they have no chance to develop. We require them to teach, so many different subjects that they can never acquire more than a text-book knowledge of them. We impose so many hours’ work and so much outside responsibility upon them that they are thoroughly wearied, when they get a few moments’ or hours’ leisure, and need all the time to recuperate their health. This complaint comes from nearly every college in the country. The faculty of Yale College asserted only a few months ago, that every professor in the institution had too much drudgery to perform. In this way we deprive ourselves, as a country, of one of the most powerful means of promoting general culture. We impress upon our professors the fact that they are first, last and all the time, primarily teachers. They are not expected to make new discoveries. We do not care to have them add to the sum total of our knowledge. All that we desire is that they shall teach our boys what is known.

So far has this spirit been carried at times, that, in a prominent institution of one of our large Western States, a professor who was busily engaged in preparing a much needed text-book, was informed that if he engaged in any more such undertakings his services would be dispensed with. In Germany things are radically different. A professor is primarily a scholar. He is expected to be a student. Only about five hours’ work a week is required of him. He can devote his time to original investigations and give the results of his labors to the world in the form of lectures. He has no responsibility of government. He has no examination papers to correct. He can lecture at the time most convenient to him, and as many hours or as few (not less than five a week, however) as he chooses. In a word, he is a man paid by the government for devoting himself to original investigation and research, with the condition of formulating his results into lectures; and indeed this is an actual aid, rather than a hindrance in his work. It compels him to put into a concise shape the result of his investigation, and enables him to present the same in a systematic form, to the consideration of a number of educated young men. How different the case of the American college professor, who stands before a class, one half of whom do not care anything about, and the rest of whom do not stand in need of, that weary quizzing of the know-nothings, which it is a part of his duty to perform. How easy it is for one to become wooden and mechanical in doing that sort of work! and no wonder either, for it is, after all, a mechanical thing.

If, then, our American theory is the correct one; viz., that it is the professor’s business to see to it that a certain number of students have committed a certain text-book to memory, which he himself has previously committed as a part of his preparation, then the dialogical (I had almost said diabolical) method is the correct one. If, on the contrary, the Germans have the right idea, if a college professor is a student, whose business it is to present the result of his studies in an impressive and attractive form to a crowd of enthusiastic and earnest learners, then the lecture system is the only valuable and practicable method of realizing this idea.

 

___________________________________

GERMAN STUDENT-LIFE

by Edmund Janes James

Source: Illinois School Journal, vol. I, no. 9 (January, 1882), pp. 13-15.

Let us look for a moment at the means at their disposal for prosecuting their studies. In the first place we have the lectures which we have already mentioned. We found that they were, for the professors, the best method of instruction. Now we may ask the question how is the lecture system adapted for the student? Can he retain what he hears so as to make it of any permanent value to him? I answer yes! Of the possibilities of the system we know almost nothing in this country. This power of retaining what one hears is a mere matter of practice. You have all heard the story of the father, who required his little boy to tell him each Sunday, what the preacher had said, and who finally succeeded in training him so that he could repeat the sermon almost word for word. The little German child is trained in the same way. Stories are read to him once, and he is required to write them out from memory and to keep up this practice until he can write almost everything he hears in a lecture of forty or fifty minutes. Such is the boy as he comes to the university. He can listen to the professor an hour, and come out and repeat the lecture substantially from beginning to end. We can not realize, I will not say the possibilities, but the actualities achieved under this system, until we have come in actual contact with them.

But even if the lecture system did not serve its end so well as it does, it might still be borne with, since it is supplemented, 1st, by private societies among the students, which are kept up by those who take an interest in some one branch, as for instance, mathematics or history. 2nd, by seminars, or small clubs conducted by the professors. I desire to call your attention especially to this feature as it has been but little noticed so far as I know by writers on German universities, and but little enjoyed by most Americans who study in Germany. In my opinion, these seminars are the most important element, in many respects, of the German university. They are but little more than methodically conducted conversations in reference to the subjects chosen for discussion. They are generally held at the house of the various professors, although, if too large, or if the professor’s house is too far away, they are held in the college building. The plan pursued varies with the subject and the professor. In the politico-economical seminar for instance, a list of subjects was generally proposed at the beginning of the term upon which essays were to be written. Each member chose one or more subjects according to his inclination, and as he had time, studied it up, and gave notice when he should read it. The members of the seminar looked up the same subject somewhat, so as to be ready for the discussion which always followed the essay. After a thorough discussion, the professor summed up what had been advanced on each side, giving his own opinion and his reasons for it.

In the philosophical seminar we read the first term, Spinoza, simply pronouncing the Latin, and if we came across a difficult sentence, stopping long enough to translate it. We would read a paragraph and the professor would stop and ask some one what he thought of that, or if that was a new idea in philosophy, first imported by Spinoza, or where did he steal that point? or who developed it after him? or, is that sound logic? &c, &c, varying his questions now and then by a biographical one. Prof. Haym, who conducted the seminars, was one of the most popular men at Halle. He was a really eloquent speaker, and his lectures on the History of Philosophy were well attended. I must relate a little incident which happened in connection with our seminar under him, and which illustrates the peculiar temperament and manner of the man. It was the close of our term on Spinoza. There had been seven of us in the club; we had met regularly at his house, and he had always set out the cigars and told the boys to help themselves. As the days grew long and warm, for it was the spring semester, he had refreshments of various sorts, and some of the boys concluded that we ought to make him some return for the pains he had taken. After due deliberation, we contributed, as heaven had blessed us, and appointed a committee to purchase a copy of Leibnitzen’s works. For some inscrutable reason which I have never been able to ascertain, the committee concluded to purchase, instead, a bust of the philosopher, Kant. “When I took my book to the professor to sign, he asked me to step into the hall and inquired if I had had anything to do with that thing, raising as he spoke, a cloth which covered a bust of the immortal Kant. “It came from my seminar, I understand. I hope it won’t be repeated. I wish to invite you to take supper with me on next Monday evening where you will meet the other members of the seminar.” At the appointed hour we had all arrived and were sitting in the parlor, expecting every moment that the professor would lead the way to the dining-room, when he slowly arose and said, “Gentlemen, I should like to see you in my study for a moment, if you please.” We followed him into his sanctum, where upon the table stood our bust of Kant. As soon as we had all come in, he turned half way toward the bust, and half toward us, and began: “Gentlemen, although I recognize your honorable intentions in making me this present, yet it has grieved me more than I can tell you, to see that you have tried to pay me off in this way. I gave you my time gladly and will do it again whenever yon feel a desire to pursue your studies on this subject further, but I am very sorry that you should attempt to get even with me in- this manner. I must therefore decline this present, in the first place, because I never accept presents, on principle. In the second place if I should accept a present, I could not take a bust. You see that I have no room for one,” and he pointed to the walls of the room, which really presented no position where a bust could be placed. ” In the third place, if I should be willing to accept a bust, I do not care for one of Kant’s, for I have one already. And finally, even if I should be willing to accept one of Kant, I should not want that, for it is really the poorest bust of Kant that has ever been made. It does not bear the slightest resemblance to him. The merchant has sold you completely. It not only does not resemble Kant, but it has no merit whatever in an artistic point of view. I asked Prof. Herzblerg to-day (who was senior professor of art in Halle) if I might put it in the university chapel, but he said he would not have it there. To save you from all loss, so far as I could, I went to the merchant who sold it to you, and he has agreed to take it back, and refund all the money but two marks, which he claims as expense for delivering and taking it back again, so here is your money; never attempt to make me a present again. Supper is ready, let us go;” and with that he led the way to the dining-room. It is needless to add, that we followed his wishes to the letter, in reference to making him presents:

It will be seen from our above description of seminar work, how valuable these seminars are as supplements to the lectures. If one joins such a society, one is sure of finding young men who are pursuing the subject in earnest, no idlers or dilettants are admitted. As they are gratuitous and private, the professors have the right to refuse admittance to any they choose, and they exercise this right pretty regularly, to keep out those whom they think wish to join for mere appearance-sake. One finds among the members, men who have been pursuing the subject from six months to three years, and consequently has from the very first, the most intimate intercourse with students who know more of the subject than himself. There is, beside, the advantage of personal contact with the professor, as the sessions are generally held at his private house.

 

___________________________________

 

 

POLITICAL ECONOMY IN GERMAN UNIVERSITIES

by Edmund Janes James

Source: The Nation, September 28, 1882. pp. 261-62.

To the Editor of The Nation:

Sir: The notice, in a recent number of the Nation of Professor Fredericq’s report on instruction in history in the German universities, suggests the thought that perhaps a short account of the instruction in political economy in these schools would be of interest to your readers. I describe the work as it is laid out in the University of Halle, both because I am better acquainted with that institution and because, in the opinion of competent critics, the work there is, on the whole, better organized than at any other similar school in Germany.

Instruction in political economy is given, in the first place, by lectures. There are three professors in this department. In the course of a year they offer several series of lectures on the following subjects: History of Political Economy, Theoretical Political Economy, Practical Political Economy (the discussion of the economic problems of modern society), Science of Finance, Statistics, Police Supervision, and Administration. lectures upon other subjects are occasionally given, especially upon economic topics of current interest.

These lectures are supplemented (1) by the politico-economic Seminar, and (2) by the politico-economic debating society. The former is organized as a department of the University; its object is to provide opportunities for those who wish to make a specialty of economics. It is a society of students under the direction of a professor. It meets for two or three hours, regularly, once a week, sometimes oftener. The exercises consist of essays by the students on subjects suggested by the director, followed by discussion and criticism of them. At the beginning of the term the professor prepares a list of subjects, theoretical, practical, and historical, from which each of the members of the Seminar chooses two or more which he agrees to present during the term. A programme is made out, and one or two of these essays assigned to each session. The subjects being known beforehand, each member of the society is expected to prepare himself for the discussion which follows the reading. Such subjects as the following are assigned: Value, Banks of Issue, Double Standard, Income-Tax, State Ownership of Railways, etc. The student is expected to know, for instance, in the first case, the opinions of all prominent economists in reference to the subject, and their definitions of it. He must be able to give reasons for his own view, accompanied with refutation of the views he rejects, etc. It will be seen that the director has an excellent opportunity in his questions to test the thoroughness and extent of the student’s investigation and to form an opinion of his ability.

The object of the society is really to promote original work in economics. A liberal amount of money is appropriated to the purchase of all recent publications of value in any language for the Seminar library. The society, although not yet fifteen years old, has done valuable original work, and its publications are rapidly acquiring an enviable reputation in Germany. A recent pamphlet by one of the members on “American Competition in European Markets” attracted the attention of the Government, and the young man who wrote it was offered a place on a commission which was to come to America and investigate the whole subject and report to the Imperial Government, but he was prevented from accepting by his election to the Reichstag. All possible assistance is given to those who aim to do original work, and the keen but sympathizing criticism of professor and fellow-student is no small aid in preventing mortifying blunders and mistakes. Professor Conrad, who now has charge of the society, is a really great teacher, able to inspire enthusiasm for his work, and wisely to direct the efforts of his students. There is also a statistical Seminar under his charge, which makes a specialty of original work in statistics.

The politico-economic debating society is under the control of the students, and discusses economic questions in the form of resolutions. It occupies itself, naturally enough, rather with practical questions of current interest than with purely theoretical problems. Its work is more serious and valuable than the work of corresponding organizations with us, because each of the members has had a tolerably complete course in political economy before he enters it.

It will be seen that the advantages offered the liberally-trained student who desires to specialize are excellent. Such a system would, of course, be of no value in our ordinary colleges, whose students need the drill and training of school-boys much more than they do opportunities for original research.

E.J. James

Normal, Ill., Sept. 12, 1882.

 

___________________________________

 

 

THE DEGREE OF PH.D. IN GERMANY

by Edmund J. James
University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, Pa.

Source: The Andover Review, vol. 9, no. 54 (June, 1888), pp. 611-623.

            The conditions on which the degree of Ph. D. should be granted has formed a subject of debate among American college authorities for some years past. The result of the discussion up to the present time has not been all that one could desire who likes uniformity in such matters as the giving of academic honors.

It may help towards its solution if we examine the condition of things in Germany at the present time in regard to this question. As is well known, the degree of Doctor of Philosophy is preeminently a German degree. It was the German universities which, by adopting it as the highest literary degree which they conferred, have given it a standing among the learned institutions of the world. It has been used in this country to so large an extent as an honorary degree, and given away so lavishly to men of high station and low station, and, indeed, of no station at all, that those who hold it on examination are almost ashamed of it, and finally, in order to defend themselves, have adopted the expedient so long in vogue in England of writing after their degrees the name of the university from which it is taken.

In the discussions on the subject which have occurred in this country it has been quite generally assumed that the conditions of granting this degree in Germany are practically uniform. This is true in a certain degree, but it is by no means true to the extent generally supposed. I propose in the following article to give a summary of the conditions required for this degree in Germany, so far as they can be deduced from the printed requirements of the various institutions, and from a somewhat extended personal investigation on my own part.

The rules and regulations of the different faculties in regard to the granting of this degree have been all collected and published by Dr. Baumgart, in a small book, dated Berlin, 1885. [3rd edition, 1888]There is a certain normal procedure in course for this degree which may be deduced by taking the requirements which are common to the larger number of universities. The requirements in the Prussian universities are somewhat more uniform than those of the other German states. For the purpose of this article, therefore, it will be best to describe the course for the Prussian degree, and then note the variations in the case of each university.

A Prussian who wishes to take the degree of Doctor of Philosophy from a Prussian university must first graduate at one of the schools which are recognized by law as entitled to prepare students for the university. These schools are of two kinds: the classical colleges or gymnasia, whose course of study, extending over nine years, is chiefly devoted to Latin, Greek, and mathematics, with some attention to history, modern languages, and natural science; and the Latin scientific, or real schools, whose course, of equal length with that of the gymnasia, differs from it in having no Greek, and giving much more attention to modern languages and natural science. After graduating at one of these schools the candidate must attend a German university for at least three years.

If he desires to come up for his degree at the earliest possible moment he must, during these three years, prepare a dissertation on some topic connected with the line of study to which he has devoted most attention. When he applies for permission to be examined for the degree he must present certificates showing his graduation from one of the above-mentioned preparatory schools, and also that he has completed the academic triennium. He must also present his dissertation, and designate two subjects in which he is willing to be examined besides philosophy, in which all candidates must pass an examination. The application must be in Latin. He must append to the dissertation certain propositions or theses which he is willing to defend against all critics. If his dissertation is considered satisfactory, and his certificates are in order, he is then admitted to an oral examination, in the presence of the faculty, on the subjects before mentioned. This examination may last from two to four hours. If the candidate successfully passes this ordeal, he must then defend his dissertation and the appended theses in public against certain specially selected critics, in some cases chosen by himself, in others appointed by the faculty. If this test is pronounced successful, he is then admitted to the formal act of graduation, and the degrees of Master of Liberal Arts and Doctor of Philosophy are conferred upon him.

Such may be called the normal course of events in the progress toward this degree. There are variations from it in almost every university, and the sum total of variations is large, though in no case is a variation made which is regarded as of vital importance. How important such deviations are, can be best seen from a comparison of the requirements of different universities with regard to each of these elements.

The course of pre-university education necessary for this degree is determined in Prussia by the State Department of Education. The government determines what schools may prepare for the university, and then carefully prescribes the course of study of such schools. Prior to 1870 only graduates of the gymnasia or classical schools were admitted to the Prussian universities. In that year the government ordered that graduates of the Latin, scientific, or ” real schools of the first order,” as they are technically called, should also be admitted to the universities in the philosophical faculty, that is, the department which includes everything but law, medicine, and theology. They are admitted to examination for the degree of Ph. D. on the same terms as the graduates of the classical colleges, except they must, of course, not choose subjects in their final examination for which a knowledge of Greek is considered necessary, such as classical philology or ancient history. The law permits students from outside of Prussia to be admitted without these certificates of graduation, on their showing to the satisfaction of the faculty that they possess the requisite maturity and mental discipline to pursue successfully university studies. As a matter of fact, no inquiry is made in regard to students from outside of Germany in regard to their qualifications. All who apply are admitted, unless they are women, or are evidently immature. If they wish to come up for degrees, the case is somewhat different, and will be noticed later.

There are twenty-one institutions within the present limit of the German empire which have power to grant the degree of Doctor of Philosophy.

Of the ten Prussian institutions only one, namely, Göttingen, makes in its rules any express distinction between the graduates of the gymnasia and the real schools. Göttingen limits the choice of subjects of the latter class, in their final examination, to mathematics, natural sciences, and modern languages. In the case of the other nine universities the same restriction certainly exists tacitly, even if they would admit candidates to a somewhat wider range of choice than the University of Göttingen. The government does not permit the graduates of real schools to present themselves for the public examination for teachers in any other branches than those mentioned in the rules of Göttingen, and while this provision does not bind the universities to make the same requirements in the case of graduation, yet the tendency to do this, it must be admitted, would naturally be very great.

Of the more important non-Prussian universities, Leipzig requires, as a rule, graduation from a gymnasium, but the faculty may, in its discretion, accept the diploma of a real school as the equivalent of the former. Erlangen and Würzburg accept the real school certificate when one of the following subjects is selected as the principal branch: mathematics, physics, chemistry, mineralogy, geology, botany, or zoology. In all other cases they require the gymnasium certificate. Freiburg requires simply “evidences of satisfactory preparation,” and reserves to the faculty the right to decide what evidences are satisfactory. As a matter of fact it accepts the two certificates as equivalent. Giessen accepts the real school certificates in the case of candidates who have chosen either natural, mathematical, political, or technical science, but requires the gymnasium certificate in other cases. Heidelberg takes much the same position as Freiburg. Jena accepts the same rule as Göttingen. Munich follows the same policy as Erlangen, except that it also grants a doctor of political science, for which it accepts real school certificates, and in general reserves to the faculty the right to accept other certificates as the equivalent of either of these. Rostock and Strasburg make no distinction between the two certificates. Tübingen grants the doctor of philosophy only in philosophy, philology, languages, and history, for which it requires the gymnasium certificate; but it also grants a doctor of science of equivalent rank, for which it accepts the real school or any equivalent certificate.

All the universities admit foreigners to the examinations if they can show by satisfactory testimonials or by examination that they possess what the faculty regard as a preparation fairly equivalent to that required of German students. Strasburg requires, however, that all candidates, whether German or foreign, shall prove their ability to translate from Greek or Latin, while the rules of Leipzig provide that, in the case of foreigners, the school and university certificates usual in the country of the candidate will be accepted, if they are sufficient to convince the faculty of the fitness of the candidate.

In general, then, it may be said that the German universities all require some knowledge of Latin, mathematics, and modern languages as a prerequisite to the degree of Ph. D. How much is required can be known from the fact that the course of the school whose certificate is accepted as unquestionably giving the necessary preparation is nine years in length, and keeps a boy busy from his ninth to his eighteenth year. On the other hand, no German university requires a knowledge of Greek for its highest literary degree, including not merely the doctor of philosophy, but also the master of arts as well. A German Ph. D. need not know one Greek letter from another, and will yet be acknowledged as entitled to the privilege of entering the academic career.

The requirement of three years’ residence at the university is made in nearly all the German universities, except those of Bavaria, where four years are required of Bavarians. The certificate of any German university is accepted by each of the other universities as fully equal to its own. Berlin and Göttingen accept the certificates of attendance not only from German universities, but also from all universities organized on the general plan of German universities. Erlangen accepts three years spent in a polytechnic school as equivalent to two of the three years required. Freiburg and Rostock accept time spent in foreign universities and foreign or domestic technical schools of high rank as equivalent, term for term, to that spent in the university. Giessen permits the faculty to make such requirements of foreigners as may seem proper to it, allowing them to dispense with testimonials of the sort required of native students. Heidelberg and Kiel do not require any definite number of years, reserving it for the faculty to decide whether the candidate has studied a satisfactory length of time. Three years is probably taken here also as the normal period. Leipzig demands, ” as a rule,” from candidates from the German empire, a certificate of three years’ attendance at some university where the German language is used as the ordinary medium, recognizing in this way the equality of Austrian, Swiss, and Germano-Russian universities. Corresponding certificates are required of foreigners, though the faculty can waive the requirement in either case. Munich and Würzburg require “evidence of several years’ study of the principal branch offered,” and at least four years in the case of Bavarian applicants. Strasburg requires at least three years in the case of native students, though the faculty is authorized to make exceptions when it may seem good to them. The rules of the other universities contain nothing at all on this point, or simply provide that three years’ attendance at a university is required.

The dissertation must be in the Latin language. Provision is made in all cases for special exceptions to be made, except when the candidate comes up for examination in ancient philology. Berlin, Bonn, Göttingen, and Königsberg prescribe that if the thesis relates to topics connected with classical and Oriental philology and antiquities or ancient history and philosophy it must be written in Latin. In all other cases the faculty may, at its discretion, accept a thesis in German, but in case it does so, the candidate may be required at the public examination to show that he can read and translate a passage assigned him from some Roman classic. Breslau and Greifswald limit the topics in which Latin must be used to classical philology and ancient history. Erlangen, Jena, Munich, Tübingen, and Würzburg allow either Latin or German, and the faculty may accept other languages. Freiburg says nothing of the language in which the thesis shall be written. Giessen allows either Latin or German, but in case of students of philology the thesis must be in one of the languages which the candidate chooses for his principal subjects. Göttingen expressly prescribes “that no translation, poems, or any other writings whose excellence consists chiefly in their rhetorical or stylistic form, nor any mere expressions of personal convictions on religious, political, aesthetic, and other questions, will be accepted. There must at least be an attempt to treat the subject in a scientific manner, either historico-critical or demonstrative.” Halle requires Latin in all cases, except “those in which the subject offers serious difficulties to the use of Latin,” and the faculty must decide whether this is true or not. Heidelberg does not require a dissertation, and is indifferent as to what language is used, if one be submitted. Kiel, Leipzig, Marburg, and Strasburg require Latin only in case the thesis relates to classical philology. The faculty of Leipzig may accept theses in other languages. Minister requires Latin only in case the thesis relates to the classical languages or literatures. Rostock requires Latin, as a rule, in the case of classical philologists; in other cases, German, English, or French will be accepted.

Freiburg, Giessen, and Jena require that the dissertation shall be truly scientific in character. Kiel requires that the dissertation shall be a science-furthering one. Konigsberg speaks of it as a “specimen of the scientific knowledge of the candidate.” Leipzig prescribes that “the dissertation will not be satisfactory unless it shows clearly that the candidate is thoroughly acquainted with the subject, and can discuss it with some independence of judgment. It must contain exact references to all the more important sources of information used by the candidate. A good form and correct language are absolutely necessary conditions.” Munich provides that in case there are any serious doubts as to the scientific value of a dissertation it is to be refused forthwith. Tübingen uses almost the same language in describing the kind of dissertation which will be satisfactory, as Leipzig. The other statutes merely call for a dissertation, or a ” scientific dissertation,” or a “dissertation on some scientific topic.” Some of the universities permit papers previously published to be used for theses, others require that they shall be specially prepared for graduation.

The oral examination comprises, as a rule, three subjects, one of which must be designated as the principal subject, and two as subordinate branches. In Munich alone, a written examination is also required. Three questions are agreed upon by the professors of the principal branch selected by the candidate, and handed, sealed, to the candidate, who must answer them, in writing, within two hours, in the presence of the Dean and one professor. The object of the oral examination is declared in the rules of Leipzig to be chiefly to ascertain in how far the special knowledge displayed in the dissertation is associated with a more comprehensive knowledge of the whole department, and of those departments most closely allied with it. In many universities philosophy and Latin are required in all such examinations. Philosophy, as used in the requirements, except where it is taken as a principal subject when it means much more, includes usually such a knowledge of logic, mental philosophy, ethics, and history of speculative philosophy as a student might get from preparing himself to pass examination in a course on each topic embracing, say sixty to ninety lectures, or in some text-book on each topic, such as we use in our American colleges. Berlin prescribes nothing as to the number of subjects chosen, but prescribes that the examination is to be conducted by four ordinary, that is, full professors, two of whom must represent the principal branch of the candidate, and every other ordinary professor shall have the right to put any questions he chooses to the candidate. This would seem to imply that the candidate will also be examined in subordinate or allied branches. The choice of subjects may be made from the whole list of subjects represented in the faculty of philosophy. In Bonn the examination consists of two parts, that looking to the degree of master of arts, and that looking toward the doctorate. In the first part the candidate is examined in philosophy, mathematics, natural sciences, ancient languages, and history. In the latter the proficiency of the candidate is tested in the special knowledge of those branches in which he professes to have made special studies. In the statutes of Bonn there is a distinct acknowledgment of the professional character of the degree of Ph. D. They say in one clause that the doctor examination differs from that for master of arts by a particularly careful and thorough test in those branches to which the candidate has specially devoted himself, and in which he thinks that he can soon begin his career as teacher. In another place they say distinctly that the degree of Ph. D., which is higher than master, may be properly conferred only on those of whom it can be truly said that they possess a tested efficiency as teachers in their branch of study. Breslau provides that the examination shall include the chief subject of the candidate, and some subordinate branches, including philosophy, and in the case of philologists history also. Erlangen prescribes that the examination shall extend to the branch to which the thesis relates as principal branch, and also to two other branches to be chosen by the candidate, and designated by him to the Dean before the examination. The choice of subjects is limited somewhat by the division of the faculty and studies. The studies are arranged in two groups, as follows: —

  1. Systematic Philosophy, History of Philosophy, Pedagogics, Classical Philology, Classical Literature, Classical Antiquities, Germanic Philology, Romanic Philology, English Philology, Oriental Philology, History, History of Art, and Political Science.
  2. Mathematics, Physics, Chemistry, Mineralogy, Geology, Botany, Zoology.

The three studies chosen may all either be taken from one group, or the candidate may take two from one and one from the other.

Freiburg prescribes three subjects to be approved by the faculty. Giessen prescribes three subjects to be chosen from the following list: Philosophy, Classical, Oriental, German, Modern Philology, History, Science of Art, Political Economy, Forestry, Agriculture, Mathematics, Physics, Chemistry, Mineralogy, Botany, Zoology. Göttingen prescribes two subjects, “which may not be mere branches of one and the same subject.”

Greifswald prescribes that every candidate must be examined in philosophy, also in his principal branch, and the appropriate subordinate branches, according to the following scheme: —

  1. If Philosophy is the principal subject, the candidate must be examined in all branches of philosophy, and one subject out of the philological-historical field, and one out of the mathematical or scientific fields.
  2. To Classical Philology belong Greek and Latin Philology and Ancient History. To German Philology, German Language and Literature, and one other historical or linguistic branch. To modern Philology, Romanic and English Philology and one other philological or historical subject. To Linguistics, comparative philology and some branch of ancient or modern Philology. To Oriental Philology, that language to which the candidate has specially devoted himself, with the allied languages of the same system, and in one branch of Classical Philology.
  3. To History, as principal subject, belong all parts of historical science, and one language.
  4. To Mathematics belong all branches of Mathematics and Physics.
  5. To Physics belong Mathematics and Chemistry.
  6. With Chemistry must be taken Physics, and any one of the descriptive Natural Sciences.
  7. With the descriptive Natural Sciences, Physics and Chemistry.
  8. With Geography, Physics, and either Mathematics, Natural Science or History.
  9. With Politics, History, History of Civilization, and Political Science.
  10. With Cameralia, Statistics, Political Science, and Industrial Science.

It will be seen that the choice in the subjects is much limited by thus grouping them together. It is significant that the faculty should think it necessary to thus prescribe the combination of subjects.

Halle prescribes three subjects, one of which must be philosophy. Heidelberg gives a list of subjects from which three must be selected by the candidate. In addition to those mentioned in the list of Erlangen, the following may be noted, — paleontology, agriculture, public law, international law, administrative law, statistics, science of administration. It is also prescribed that in case such a subject is taken as Shemitic languages, for example, a thorough knowledge of at least one language will be required, and a general acquaintance with all the languages of the group. It is furthermore provided that, besides the subjects given in this list, parts of them, or branches, or allied sciences, may be chosen as secondary subjects. But in such cases a more thorough knowledge of the subject will be demanded. It will be seen from this that a candidate can practically limit himself to one subject in his examination, and still get his degree. Jena gives a list of seventeen subjects from which a choice of three must be made. The list is similar to that of Erlangen. Königsberg prescribes that the candidate shall be examined chiefly in the subjects to which ho has specially devoted himself, but every professor has the right to put questions in other branches also, particularly philosophy, philology, history, mathematics, and natural sciences. Leipzig requires three subjects, which shall be related to each other, and shall be selected with due regard to the wishes of the candidate. Marburg prescribes philosophy and the subjects allied to the chief subject selected by the candidate. Munich prescribes three subjects, and gives a list of eighteen from which the choice is to be made, but reserves to the faculty the right to accept others, or parts of others, if the candidate wishes it. Münster prescribes four subjects, one of which must be philosophy. If the chief subject is philosophy, the other three may be selected by the candidate, with the restriction that one at least must come from philology or history, and one from mathematics or natural science. If the chief subject is one of the classical languages, the other must be offered also. If German, then history. If a Romanic language, then Latin. If English, then German. If Sanskrit, Latin or German. If history, then Latin. If art, political economy, or related sciences; the choice of the other subjects is free. The choice of the fourth subject is free, but is limited to one of the foregoing subjects. If the chief subject is mathematics, physics or astronomy must be offered. If physics or astronomy, then mathematics. If chemistry, then physics. If one of the descriptive natural sciences, then at least another of these same sciences. The choice of the fourth subject is free. Rostock prescribes three subjects, and gives a list of seventeen from which they must be chosen. It is interesting to note that whereas Rostock gives political science as one of the subjects of three which must be chosen, Heidelberg divides the subject so that one can limit himself to political science. Strasburg prescribes three subjects, and that candidates in classical philology shall be examined in Latin, that is, that language used in the examination, and that all candidates shall be examined in the translation of a Latin author. Tübingen prescribes two subjects only, and faculty may excuse from oral examination. Würzburg prescribes the combinations, any one of which may be chosen for the examination. They closely resemble those given above for Greifswald.

A public disputation or defense of the thesis, and the appended theses, is absolutely required at Berlin after the oral examination. The disputation is to be in Latin, except when the faculty gives permission to use German. Bonn prescribes that among the opponents of the candidate in this public debate there shall be at least one ordinary professor appointed by the faculty for this purpose, and who closes the side opposed to the candidate. Latin must be used in the disputation when the thesis is required in Latin. Erlangen, Leipzig, Freiburg, Giessen, Greifswald, Heidelberg, Jena, Rostock, Strasburg, and Tübingen do not require a public disputation. Göttingen allows the candidate his choice between a public ceremony, to which the public disputation belongs, or a private ceremony in a committee of the faculty, without disputation. Halle requires a public disputation by all who wish to enter a Prussian university as privat docenten. Other candidates may dispense with this ceremony. Kiel requires the candidate to deliver a short lecture on some topic chosen by himself, and make a public defense of his dissertation and appended theses, though the faculty may dispense with the defense of the dissertation. Königsberg, Munich, Münster, Würzburg, require a public disputation. The faculty of Marburg may excuse from the disputation at the request of the candidate.

The graduation ceremony is, at different universities, quite different, and on different occasions, at the same university, depending often, as described above in the case of Göttingen, on the wish of the candidate. It varies from a very solemn and ceremonious act, with a procession of members of the faculty in full academic costume, to the mere handing over to the candidate of his diploma by the Dean of the faculty, in a private room, in the presence of two or three professors.

The degree of Ph. D. is not granted by any of the universities in absentia, except when it is honoris causa. Bonn allows the faculty to grant the doctor’s degree ” without examination, only as a voluntary acknowledgment of excellent services to science. In very exceptional cases it may also be granted to show respect of the faculty for other than scientific services.” Würzburg also provides in the published rules for degrees honoris causa, in case two thirds of the corresponding committee of the faculty agree to it. The rules of the other faculties say nothing of such graduations, but in nearly all of them the degree is granted honoris causa, but, as a rule, only in the case of distinguished services to science.

The rules of Halle prescribe that “whoever wishes the degrees of Master of Arts and Doctor of Philosophy must not only possess that general culture which is necessary to any high degree of scholarship, but must also have pursued with success some branch of science which is represented in the philosophical faculty. The certificate of graduation from a gymnasium or real school testifies to the former, and the dissertation and examination before the faculty to the latter.”

A careful consideration of the foregoing provisions will give one a clear idea of the conditions of the German Ph. D. It is evident that any boy of good abilities and good health, who can go to school from the beginning of his seventh year, can attain to the degrees of Master of Arts and Doctor of Philosophy by the close of his twenty-first year, having divided his time as follows: three years in the primary school, nine years in the gymnasium, and three years in the university. As a matter of fact, owing to the circumstance that the average age of those who graduate from the gymnasium and real school is about nineteen, and that the average student spends much of the time at the university, during the first year, in recreation, thus requiring another year to complete his course, he will not get his degrees before he is twenty-three or four.

When we compare this condition of circumstances with that prevailing in American colleges, most of us will, I am sure, be surprised at the result. If we take any of our leading colleges we shall find that twenty is below the average age at which the classes leave college, and that if the college gives the doctor’s degree on examination, it usually prescribes at least two years’ further study, bringing the lowest age at which this degree is granted to at least twenty-two. The average age of some of the recent graduating classes at Harvard College was twenty-three and one half. Counting two years more as necessary for the degree, candidates would be on the average twenty-five and one half before they would be admitted to the examination. In some of the other colleges, where the average age is at least one or one and one-half years younger, as at the University of Pennsylvania, the age of applicants would still be twenty-three or twenty-four, — the same age as that of the German applicants.

One can also get a pretty clear idea as to the extent and severity of the examinations for the degree. They certainly cannot fairly require more in the way of knowledge than what a man can acquire within three years faithfully devoted to study. This means, of course, very much more in some studies than in others, owing to the place which certain lines of study hold in the preparatory course of study. Thus the gymnasium course is a special preparation for the course in philology, and it is, of course, perfectly fair to require of the candidate in this department a much more extensive knowledge of his subject than in political economy, for example, where all the candidate knows of the subject is what he has acquired in his three years’ course.

Taken all in all, it is pretty certain that it requires more hard work to get the degree of Ph. D. from a good American college, requiring post-graduate residence for two years, than from a German university. Why is it that the latter is considered of more value? This can only be answered after a discussion of the different conditions under which the two degrees are acquired, which would take a lengthy article for itself.

 

Image Source:  Edmund Janes James: Twelfth President of the Economic Association, 1910American Economic Review, Vol. 34, No. 3 (September 1944).

Categories
Gender Germany

Berlin. Mansplaining economics, 1895

While surfing through some early volumes (1890-1895) of The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, I stumbled across the following announcement for a Berlin set of a dozen public courses to be held by distinguished scholars (of course the courses would have been offered in German, but it is handy here to have everything translated).

What simply caught my eye is highlighted below in boldface.

My question to anyone who sees this: what do you think was meant by putting the quotation marks around others, including educated women beyond of course indicating that this was an exact translation from the announcement? Was it a serious “Look, they let women attend!” or perhaps an ironic statement “Note, there must be no women lawyers, clergy, teachers, public officials, or journalists!” or worse still “What, women can attend?”

Please add your opinions below to the comments section.

 ______________________________________

Notes

[…]

THE GERMAN VEREIN FÜR SOZIALPOLITIK decided on the 17th of March of this year to organize a vacation course of lectures in Political and Social Science, to be held in the buildings of the University of Berlin from the 30th of September to the 12th of October. The people for whom these lectures are primarily intended are lawyers, clergymen, teachers, public officials of all classes, journalists, and “others, including educated women.” Twelve courses of six lectures each have been arranged. The price of an inclusive ticket has been fixed at 25 marks; the price for any one week for all lectures given in that week at 15 marks, and for the single course of six lectures at 3 marks.

Professor Conrad, of the University of Halle, will give one course on “Population, Colonies and Emigration ;”
Professor v. Miaskowski, of Leipsic, on “The Establishment, Preservation and Extension of the German Peasant Class;”
Professor v. Philippovich, of Vienna, on “Recent Commercial Policy;”
Professor Brentano, of Munich, on “The Wages Question;”
Professor Knapp, of Strassburg, on “Money ;”
Professor Neumann, of Tübingen, on “Finance;”
Professor Sering, of Berlin, on “Agriculture;”
Professor Bücher, of Leipsic, on “Modern Industry;”
Professor Wagner, of Berlin, on “Private Property;”
Professor Elster, of Breslau, on “Social Problems of the Modern State;”
Dr. Oldenberg, of Berlin, on “History and Theory of the Social Democracy;”
Professor Schmoller, of Berlin, on “Social Classes and Social Struggles.”

 

Source: The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science. Vol. 6 (July, 1895), pp. 163-164.

 

Image Source: Playbill for The New Woman (1894) by Sydney Grundy. From the Sally Fox Collection. Radcliffe Institute for Advanced Study, Harvard University.

Categories
Economists

Cambridge. Alfred Marshall on Economics at American Universities, 1893

_________________

Actually the admiration turns out to have been mutual.

_________________

Perhaps I may be allowed to end with an Englishman’s expression of admiration, tinged perhaps a little with envy, at the generous opportunities which the rapidly growing number of American universities is offering for advanced economic study, and at the zeal and ability with which these opportunities are being turned to account.

Alfred Marshall

Cambridge, England.

 

Source: Concluding paragraph of Alfred Marshall’s response to an article by Simon Patten: “Consumer’s Surplus,” The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, Vol. 3 (March, 1893), pp. 90-93.

Image Source: Alfred Marshall by Walter Stoneman (1917). National Portrait Gallery,   NPG x25013. Creative Commons license.

Categories
Economists Exam Questions M.I.T. Suggested Reading Syllabus

MIT. Robert Solow’s Advanced Economic Theory Course, 1962

Robert Solow taught the course Advanced Economic Theory at MIT in the Spring of the 1961/62 academic year. Of the dozen graduate students who took the course for credit were a future Nobel prize winner (Peter Diamond), a future Princeton professor and later member of Jimmy Carter’s Council of Economic Advisers (Stephen Goldfeld), a future professor at University of Pennsylvania/Washington University (Robert Pollak), a future professor and later chairman of Hebrew University (David Levhari), and a professor of economics and the first woman to head an MIT academic department, economics! 1984-1990 and MIT’s first female academic dean, School of Humanities and Social Science (Ann Friedlaender).

The three A’s awarded in the course went to Diamond, Levhari and Goldfeld.

The comprehensive exam questions for advanced economic theory from May 1962 were transcribed in the previous post.

_____________________________________

 

14.123—Advanced Economic Theory
Spring 1962—Professor Solow

FIRST READING LIST: LINEAR PROGRAMMING AND RELATED SUBJECTS

This should occupy 6-9 weeks. Most of the reading is in Gale: The Theory of Linear Economic Models and Dorfman, Samuelson, Solow: Linear Programming and Econmic Analysis, referred to below as G and D respectively.

  1. Mathematical background: I hope to avoid spending any time on this. Mainly elements of matrix algebra—14.102 should be enough. For review, see D (Appendix B) and G (Ch. 2, more difficult).
  2. Elements of Linear Programming; D (Ch. 2,3), G (Ch. 1,3).
  3. Algebra and Geometry of Linear Programming, Simplex Method; D (Ch. 4, Sec. 1-11), G (Ch. 4).
  4. Applications; D (Ch. 5-7), Manne: Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (Ch. 4,5).
  5. Two-person zero-sum games; D (Ch. 15), G (Ch. 6,7).
  6. Leontief and similar systems; G (Ch. 8, 9 Sec. 1-3), D (Ch. 9, 10).
  7. Activity analysis; G (Ch. 9, Sec. 4), Koopmans: Three Essays on the State of Economic Science (pp. 66-104).
  8. Von Neumann’s model; D (Ch. 13, Sec. 6), G (Ch. 9, Sec. 5-7).
  9. Sraffa: Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities.
    Robinson: “Prelude to a Critique of Economic Theory”, Oxford Economic Papers, February 1961, 53-58.
  10. If time permits, the turnpike theorem; D (Ch. 12), Hicks: “Prices and the Turnpike”, Review of Economic Studies, February 1961, 77-88.
    Radner: “Paths of Economic Growth that are Optimal, etc.”, Review of Economic Studies, February 1961, 98-104.

(Further references may follow.)

 

SECOND READING LIST: PUBLIC INVESTMENT CRITERIA

  1. Hirshleifer: “On the Theory of Optimal Investment Decision”, Journal of Political Economy, August 1958, pp. 329-352.
  2. Graaff: Theoretical Welfare Economics, Chs. 6-8.
  3. Eckstein: “A Survey of the Theory of Public Expenditure Criteria”, in Public Finances: Needs, Sources and Utilization, with “Comments” by Hirshleifer.
  4. Margolis: “The Economic Evaluation of Federal Water Resource Development”, AER, March 1959, pp. 96-111.
  5. Steiner: “Choosing Among Alternative Public Investments”, AER, Dec. 1959, pp. 898-916.
  6. Maass, al.: Design of Water-Resource Systems, Chs. 2, 13 (and passim).
  7. Eckstein: Water Resource Development, Ch. 1-4.

_____________________________________

April 11, 1962

14.123—Exam

Answer all questions.

  1. A function f of vectors x,y,… is called subadditive if f(x+y) ≤ f(x) + f(y) for all vectors x, y, and called superadditive if the inequality is reversed.
    Consider the LP problem of maximizing C′x subject to Ax ≤ b. The value of the maximum is a function of C, b, and A. Show that it is a subadditive function of C and a superadditive function of b.
  2. A firm can produce n commodities with a linear technology involving one activity for each commodity. Production involves only fixed factors, m in number, m<n, of which specified amounts are available. The output is sold at market prices p, and the firm chooses non-negative vector x of outputs to maximize p′x subject to the fixed-factor limitations.
    (a) Prove that the supply curve is not negatively sloped; that is, prove that if p1 increases, other prices constant, the optimal x1 must increase or remain unchanged, but cannot decrease. (Hint: a straightforward procedure is to consider closely the final simplex tableau, the signs of various elements, and what can happen to require further iteration if p1 There is a much simpler proof, comparing the before-and-after optima.)
    (b) State and interpret the dual to the theorem just proved.
  3. Consider a simple linear model of production, with 2 goods, and with 2 fixed factors, land and labor, available in specified amounts.
    (a) Sketch possible shapes for the set of feasible net outputs, or net production-possibility curve.
    (b) Suppose demand conditions are such that consumption expenditures on the two commodities are always equal. Give a complete analysis of the determination of the prices of the two goods and also the rent of land and the wage of labor. Graphical methods will help. (Hint: at one key point the construction of an isosceles triangle is very useful.)

 

Source: Duke University. Rosenstein Library. Robert M. Solow Papers, Box 67, Folder “14.123 Final Exam Fall-1969[sic|”.

Image Source: Robert Merton Solow at the M.I.T. Museum website.

Categories
Exam Questions M.I.T.

MIT. Advanced Economic Theory Exam, 1962

Coming up will be the reading list(s) and exam for the course Economics 14.123 (Advanced Economic Theory) taught by Robert Solow in the Spring semester of the 1961-62 academic year at M.I.T. 

_____________________

May, 1962

GENERAL EXAMINATION—ADVANCED THEORY

Answer question 1 and 3 others.

  1. Make a catalog of the kinds of situations in which resource allocation through the price system is likely to give non-optimal results. Indicate the nature of the non-optimality, and for at least some of the situations describe the analytic reason why non-optimality results.

 

  1. A consumer can buy n goods, x1 … xn, at prices p1, … pn. For each unit of xi he purchases (for cash), he receives ai trading stamps. He may then purchase further commodities for trading stamps at fixed trading-stamp prices w1 … wn.

Analyze his equilibrium in each of the following cases, interpreting your results in words and explaining how the equilibrium differs (if at all) from the no-trading-stamp equilibrium where all ai = 0.

(a) ai = k pi; wi = c pi

(b) ai = k pi; wi ≠ c pi

(c) ai ≠ k pi; wi = c pi

(d) ai ≠ k pi; wi ≠ c pi

 

  1. Let A be a non-singular, indecomposable constant Leontief matrix. If this period’s outputs are immediately and exactly plowed back as inputs for next period and there is no capital or consumption:

(a) Set up the implied difference equation system.

(b) Is that system capable of balanced growth?

(c) Under what conditions will it be balanced growth rather than balanced decay?

(d) Is the balanced growth ray unique?

(e) What optimality properties, if any, does balanced growth have?

(f) Is the balanced growth ray stable?

 

  1. There are k countries, each with a fixed supply of a single scarce primary factor of production. In country i, it takes ai units of the factor to produce a unit of wine and bi units to product a unit of cloth.

(a) Formulate this k-country Ricardian comparative advantage setup as a linear programming problem for world efficiency, and show how the Ricardian results emerge.

(b) State and interpret the dual of the world-efficiency problem.

 

  1. An investor has open to him all two-period investment options with net cash flows N0 and N1 such that  N02 + N12 =1. He can lend unlimited amounts at an interest rate of 4 percent per period and borrow unlimited amounts at a rate of 6 percent per period. His preference for consumption in the two periods C0 and C1 are described by the utility function U = C0 +(C1)½. Find the investor’s best plan of action.

 

  1. A system uses primary labor and produced capital good(s) to produce consumption output and gross capital formation(s). Labor grows exponentially at the rate of g per annum. Suppose everything else matches that rate of growth. Show that consumption per capita is maximized where the interest rate, r, equals the growth rate, g. (Use any specific model, however simple or complex, to give your proof.)

 

Source: Duke University. Rubenstein Library. Edwin Burmeister Papers. Box 23.

Image Source: MIT beaver from the cover of the 1949 yearbook Technique.

Categories
Courses Harvard Suggested Reading Syllabus

Harvard. Problems of Labor. William Z. Ripley, 1931

 

 

William Zebina Ripley (1867-1941) was awarded a B.S. in civil engineering from M.I.T. in 1890. With his dissertation “The Financial History of Virginia, 1607-1776”  he earned a doctorate in political economy at Columbia University in 1893. His initial reputation was based on his work The Races of Europe: A Sociological Study (1899)  that ascribed civic and moral characteristics of peoples to their racial characteristics. Like many in the populist right today who worry about the impact of immigrants on the existing domestic culture, Ripley too saw social behaviors as essentially hard-wired. He moved on from his racist social anthropology to become an expert on railroad affairs, labor market institutions and the regulation of financial markets (Main Street and Wall Street (1927)).  He ended policy-wise closer to the Occupy Wall Street movement than one might have expected from his early scholarship.

A brief biographical entry for Ripley written by Paul J. Miranti Jr.’s was published in History of Accounting: An International Encyclopedia. 1996, pp. 502-505.

The reading list in today’s post comes from a folder of economics reading lists for the Harvard economics department from the academic year 1931-32. While penciled in at the top of the page is “Econ 34”, the typed header reads “Assignments for Economics 10”. As seen from the enrollment report for Economics 34, William Z. Ripley was credited with teaching that class. The reading assignments are clearly for a course in labor economics (as opposed to the Economics 10a and 10b, economic history courses taught by Usher that year). There was no previous course numbering system in which Economics 10 was a labor economics course either. Thus, I am puzzled about the origin of this reading list. Maybe “Economics 10” was simply a secretarial typo.

________________________________

 

Course Enrollment

[Economics] 34. Professor Ripley.—Problems of Labor.

3 Graduates, 1 Radcliffe, 1 Other: Total 5

 

Source: Harvard University. Report of the President of Harvard College and Reports of Departments, 1931-32, p. 72.

________________________________

 

Econ 34

Assignments for Economics 10 [sic]
1931

I. INTRODUCTION; THE WAGE SYSTEM AND DOCTRINES OF WAGES.

Final Report of the Commission on Industrial Relations, 1915, pp. 22-91; pp. 407-439. [pencil note: “either of these the 1st day; the other the 2nd day.”]
Bogart, Economic History of the United States, ch. 4.
Mill, Principles of Political Economy, book II, chs. 5,11.
Marshall, Principles of Economics, book VI, chs. 1-5.

II. LABOR ORGANIZATION.

  1. Collective Bargaining; Employers’ Associations.

Webb, Industrial Democracy, part II, ch. 2.
Hoxie, Trade Unionism in the United States, chs. 8, 10.
Commons, Trade Unionism and Labor Problems, ch. 39.

  1. Trade Union Policies and Activities

Hoxie, ch. 11.
Furniss, Labor Problems, ch. 10
Watkins, Labor Problems, ch. 20.
Estey, The Labor Problem, ch. 3.

(a) The Closed Shop.

Estey, ch. 5.
Catlin, ch. 12.

(b) The Standard Rate; Opposition to Piece Rates.

Webb, Part II, ch. 5.
Hoxie, ch. 13.

(c) The Normal Day

Webb, part II, ch. 6.

(d) Restriction of Output

Catlin, ch. 13.

(e) Union Attitude toward Machinery; Technological Unemployment.

Webb, part II, ch. 8.
Watkins, ch. 5.

(f) Mutual Assistance (Benefits)

Catlin, ch. 14.

(g) Labor Banks.

Hardman, American Labor Dynamics, ch. 28.

(h) The Closed Union.

Webb, part II, ch. 10, section (a) and part III, ch. 3, section (a).

  1. Historical Background

Webb, History of Trade Unionism.
Furniss, ch. 8.
Hoxie, ch. 4.
Wolman, Growth of American Trade Unions.
Ware, The Labor Movement in the United States, 1860-1895.
Perlman, History of Trade Unionism in the United States.
Mary Beard, A Short History of the American Labor Movement.

(a) The Early Years.

(b) The Knights of Labor.

(c) The Development of Craft Unionism.

  1. Trade Unionism vs. Industrial Unionism

Hoxie, ch. 6.
American Mercury, March, 1929, Earl W. Shimmons, “The Twilight of the A. F. of L.”

  1. Trade-union Problems.

(a) Organization of the A. F. of L.

Hoxie, ch. 5.
Furniss, ch. 9.
Matthew Woll, The American Federation of Labor.

(b) The Amalgamated Clothing Workers of America and the Railroad Brotherhoods.

(c) Trade Union Organization Abroad. (Great Britain, Germany, France, Russia, Italy, Australasia, Canada, Latin America).

Catlin, The Labor Problem, ch. 10.
Raynor, Trade Unionism.
Dunn, Soviet Trade Unions.
Beals, Rome or Death, ch. 10.
Logan, Trade-union Organization in Canada, ch. 4.
Journal of Political Economy, June 1930, M. R. Clark, “French Syndicalism of the Present.”

(d) Problems of Organization.

Hoxie, ch. 7.
Hardman, American Labor Dynamics, chs. 6,7.

(e) Unionism in the South.

Hardman, ch. 18.
Wm. Green, Labor’s Message to the South.
American Mercury, Feb. 1930, W. J. Cash, “The War in the South.”

(f) Violence in Labor Disputes.

United States Commission on Industrial Relations, 1915.
Helen Marot, American Labor Unions.

  1. Organized Labor and the Courts.

Hoxie, ch. 9.
Furniss, ch. 12.
Commons and Andrews, Principles of Labor Legislation, ch. 3, section 1.
Blum, Labor Economics, chs. 4, 5.
Sayre, Cases on Labor Law.

(a) The Strike and the Boycott.

Catlin, ch. 15.
Groat, Organized Labor in America, chs. 10, 11, 14, 15.

(b) Picketing

(c) The Injunction.

(d) Legal Status of Trade Unions.

  1. Labor and Politics: Policy of the A. F. of L.

Furniss, ch. 11.
Hardman, ch. 22.
Samuel Gompers, Should a Political Labor Party be Formed?

  1. Conciliation, Mediation, and Arbitration.

Webb, part II, ch. 3.
Furniss, ch. 13.
Blum, pp. 248-291.
Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 31, M. B. Hammond, “The Regulation of Wages in New Zealand.”

(a) Compulsory Mediation; The Lemieux Act (Canada).

(b) Compulsory Arbitration in New Zealand and Germany.

[handwritten addition in pen: Pol. Sci. Quarterly, Sept. ’29, H. B. Davis, “The German Labor Courts”)]

  1. Industrial Relations.

Gemmill, Present Day Labor Relations.
Furniss, chs. 14, 15.
Hardman, chs. 19, 20, 21.

(a) The Company Union; Employee Representation; Attitude of Organized Labor.

(b) Trade-union Management.

(c) Profit-sharing and Ownership-sharing.

III. UNEMPLOYMENT.

  1. The Problem of Unemployment

Fairchild, Furniss, and Buck, Elementary Economics, ch. 48.
Furniss, Labor Problems, ch. 2.
Blum, Labor Economics, ch. 8.
Cassel, Theory of Social Economy, ch. 15.

  1. Remedies for Unemployment.

Furniss, ch. 3.
Blum, chs. 9, 10.

IV. SOCIAL LEGISLATION.

Webb, part II, ch. 4.
Sayre, Cases on Labor Law.

  1. Industrial Accidents; Workmen’s Compensation Acts.

Furniss, ch. 7.
Commons and Andrews, pp. 434-453.

  1. The Minimum Wage.

Furniss, ch. 4.
Journal of Political Economy, Dec. 1912, Webb, “Theory of the Legal Minimum Wage.”
Commons, Trade Unionism and Labor Problems. ch. 42.

  1. Hours of Labor.

Furniss, ch. 5.

  1. Unemployment and Sickness Insurance.

Commons, Trade Unionism and Labor Problems, chs. 3, 4.

  1. Old-age Pensions.

  2. Child and Woman Labor.

Furniss, ch. 6.

V. SCHEMES OF SOCIAL REFORM.

Hoxie, ch. 14.
Manifesto of the Communist Party.
Lindsay, Karl Marx’s Capital.

  1. The Co-operative Movement.

Catlin, ch. 22.

  1. Communism, Anarchism and Socialism.

Lorwin, Labor and Internationalism, chs. 16, 17, 21, 22

  1. The Single Tax.

  2. Socialist Parties in the United States.

VI. MISCELLANEOUS PROBLEMS OF LABOR.

  1. The International Labor Organization of the League of Nations.

  2. The Labor Turnover.

Estey, ch. 10.
Commons, Trade Unionism and Labor Problems, ch. 12.

  1. Immigration.

Watkins, ch. 35.

  1. Credit Unions as a Factor in Improving Living Conditions among the Working Classes.

American Federationist, Jan. 1930, Roy F. Bergengren, “The Credit Union.”
Edson L. Whitney, Co-operative Credit Societies (Credit Unions) in America and in Foreign Countries.

  1. Recent Trend of Real Wages.

VII. CONCLUSION.

Hamilton and May, Control of Wages

 

 

Source: Harvard University Archives. Syllabi, course outlines and reading lists in Economics, 1895-2003. Box 2, Folder “Economics, 1931-1932”.