Categories
Exam Questions M.I.T.

M.I.T. Midterm and Final exams. Income and Employment Theory. Domar, 1968-69

 

Previously posted are the outlines, readings, and exams for Domar’s national income and employment courses taught at the University of Chicago in 1948 and at M.I.T. in 1965. Also of interest here are the MIT student evaluations for this and other core theory courses in the late 1960s.

There is little doubt in my mind that MIT economics graduate students during the first term of the 1968-69 academic year responded to Evsey Domar’s attempts to get them interested in the details of national income and product accounting and productivity indexes with an enthusiasm to rival the high-school kids’ reaction to the Hawley-Smoot lesson attempted by a high-school teacher in the cult-film Ferris Bueller’s Day Off.

Fun-fact: the boring teacher in the movie was played by Ben Stein, son of economist, Herbert Stein. One more piece of fun: watch an older Ben Stein talk about getting that role.

In Domar’s defense, national accounting and index numbers have never been the stuff of a great TED talk. Anyone? … Anyone?

__________________

THE THEORY OF INCOME AND EMPLOYMENT
14.451
E. D. Domar

MIDTERM EXAMINATION
November 27, 1968

Seventy-five minutes

Please answer all questions. Note their weights. Use a separate book for each question.

  1. [30%] “One of the basic defects of the American economic system lies in the presence of a large number of persons who receive legal incomes and yet perform no useful services. The inclusion of their incomes in the national income total (according to accepted methods) undoubtedly exaggerates this total.”
    Discuss this statement carefully. Distinguish different kinds of income and different sources. In each case indicate how national income (or product) will be affected if these persons were employed productively. (What does “productively” mean in this context?)
  2. [30%] In national income comparisons between the Soviet Union and the U.S. (or other pairs of less developed and advanced countries) it is usually thought that existing methods of social accounting understate the ratio of Russian to American income, particularly if official rates of exchange are used for conversion.
    1. Evaluate this statement critically and indicate whether or not you agree with it and why.
    2. Suppose the comparison was made first in Russian prices (for both countries) and then in American prices (again for both countries). Which one should give the Russians a more favorable ratio and why? (Hint: consider comparisons over time in the same country.)Note: Disregard the complexities of the Russian price system: remember that the Russian ruble is not freely convertible into other currencies.
  3. [25%] a. What role or roles does the so-called “Money Illusion” play in the Classical and Keynesian systems?

b. If a country is suffering from inflation, will an increase in output brought about by the reduction in unemployment (assuming that it existed) intensify or reduce the inflation? Why? (Hint: this is not an easy question; consider carefully the nature of output to be produced.)

  1. [15%] If you wanted to measure labor or other factor productivity would you or would you not use the Federal Reserve Index of Industrial Production? Why or why not?

 

Source: Duke University. David M. Rubenstein Rare Book and Manuscript Library. Economists’ Papers Archives. Evsey D. Domar Papers. Box 17, Folder “Macroeconomics Examinations (1 of 3)”.

__________________

THE THEORY OF INCOME AND EMPLOYMENT
14.451
E. D. Domar

FINAL EXAMINATION
Jan. 28, 1969

Three hours

Please answer Question 1 and any FOUR out of the five remaining questions. Use a separate book for each question.

  1. [24%] An overheard argument among students in 14.451 about measures required to increase investment:

Student A: Increase the quantity of money in order to reduce the rate of interest.

Student B: No, an increase in the quantity of money will merely raise prices.

Student C: A fall in the rate of interest will not have any appreciable effect on investment in any case.

Student D: A fall in the rate of interest will reduce savings, and thus reduce rather than increase investment.

Student E: To increase investment we should increase savings by increasing income inequality.

Student F: On the contrary, greater income equality will increase savings.

Student G: You are both (That is, E and F) wrong: the fraction of income saved is independent of income distribution and of the size of a person’s income.

Student H: To increase investment we should increase demand by increasing consumption and thus reducing saving.

Student I: Nothing will help unless you reduce the prices of machinery and construction.

Student J: You (that is, Student I) are wrong: your suggestion will merely reduce the amount of investment.

Please set this poor, confused group straight (if you can). In so doing, explain clearly the assumptions and conditions implied in each statement and evaluate it critically. Try to identify the opera (and its author) from which each aria is taken. How would you go about increasing investment?

  1. [19%] “Thus the rate of interest is what it is because it is expected to become other than it is; if it is not expected to become other than it is, there is nothing left to tell us what it is…”
    1. Can you identify the author of this famous statement?
    2. Can you recognize whose interest theory he referred to?
    3. Explain and evaluate that theory critically.
    4. Present your own (original or otherwise) theory of interest.
  2. [19%] a. Assume that all expenditures on education and training, both private and public, are to be treated as investment. Explain the modifications that you would make in existing methods of national income, (and product) and wealth accounting and the reasons for these changes.

b. In computing national product, each commodity (or service) is multiplied by its price in order to compute the total. What is the rationale for this method? What assumptions is it based on? Are these assumptions realistic?

  1. [19%] Suppose Project I has a higher internal rate of return, while Project II has a larger discounted value. Assume that the projects are mutually exclusive, and that both are being considered by a private firm.
    1. Explain the rationale of each method and the assumptions it is based on.
    2. Which method (that is, the internal rate vs. present value) would you use under what conditions and why?
    3. How will your calculations be changed if the projects are undertaken by a government of some underdeveloped country?
  2. [19%] a. “A high ratio of depreciation to investment is a sign of old age.”

b. “If the measured distribution of income remained the same in the U.S. over the last fifty years, the distribution of permanent income has become less equal.”
Comment. Explain your conclusion thoroughly.
c. “If the Balanced-Budget Theorem is correct, is Say’s Law also correct?”
Comment. Explain what is meant by each part of this statement.

  1. [19%] a. “What is the proper definition of money required in the Price-Flexibility (Patinkin-like) problems? Why and how does it differ from the usual definition?
    Explain what elements of American money supply and of other relevant assets you would include or exclude in the proper (for this purpose) definition of money.

b. Explain how Patinkin’s conclusions regarding the effects of an increase (say, of doubling) in the quantity of money “by magic” on the price level and on the rate of interest are modified by the existence of the money illusion in the labor market.
c. Assume the absence of money illusion and explain why the effects of creating money by open market operations differ from those when money is created “by magic.”

 

Source:Duke University. David M. Rubenstein Rare Book and Manuscript Library. Economists’ Papers Archives. Evsey D. Domar Papers. Box 17, Folder “Macroeconomics Examinations (2 of 3)”.

Image Source: Evsey D. Domar at the MIT Museum.

Categories
Funny Business M.I.T.

M.I.T. Economics Christmas skit with basketball theme, 1961

 

Spoiler alert: you are about to encounter one of the least funny economics skits in the history of the genre, so this artifact is regrettably low on entertainment value.  Still the six acts have a certain seven-acts-of-man structure: Act I (the department recruits), Act II ( advising the first-year student), Act III (graduate student complaints), Act IV (choosing guest speakers), Act V (general examinations), Act VI (job market). 

After reading the skit, you might need a palate cleansing or better: for that purpose here are a few links to the key word “Funny Business” at Economics in the Rear-view Mirror that take you to some of the greatest hits of economics skits.

____________________

ANOTHER TWO POINTS FOR THE FACULTY,
ANOTHER FOUL ON THE STUDENTS

A Christmas Drama (with suggestions for a cast), December 15, 1961

ACT I

(The curtain rises on a scene of [Edgar Cary] Brown, [Franklin Marvin] Fisher, [Charles Poor] Kindleberger and [Abraham J.] Siegel seated around a table reading applications.

SIEGEL: Here’s a guy who may be OK…No…the place is no good. A cow college. They average only 50 points a game.

BROWN:  Here’s a good one.

FISHER: What’s his record?

BROWN: Pretty darn good. Worth at least tuition plus $500. Maybe $750.

FISHER: What’s his record?

BROWN: Pretty darn good. He’s from Podunk. And they’re pretty good. He was the best they had.

FISHER: How did he score, for crying out loud?

BROWN: He’s six-feet-five, weighs 195 pounds, and fast; he averaged 23.7 points a game. He has a great set shot, never misses from the foul line, and superb off the backboard. He’s just what we need in Graduate Economics at M.I.T.

 

ACT II

(An office: Siegel is advising a student.)

SIEGEL: For the first year I would take pretty standard fare: theory, history, statistics, finance, and international, plus of course the workshop. There’s no use trying to take too much. Pace yourself.

STUDENT (perhaps [Stephen Herbert] Hymer?): I don’t have much math. Why do I need to take statistics?

SIEGEL: Ando is very good. He doesn’t always make things completely clear, but you have to take statistics if you want to be able to handle averages, to work out the point per game and point per shot records; and you need probability to help compute odds on all the league games. Statistics is a must.

STUDENT: Why the history, finance and international?

SIEGEL: International is important. You ought to know how to schedule the Harlem Globetrotters, and who has the best chance in the Olympics. One of our best graduates played on the Oxford team against Poland and Czechoslovakia. That was Chuck Cooper, and it got him a job as Walter Heller’s assistant at the Council. Finance is important. When the gamblers start bribing players you need to know how to invest the funds. And history is vital. On the general exams they always ask who was James Naismith, the man who invented basketball. That’s for every student. The good students they ask when it was invented…of course 1891. And the very best students they ask where…past, Springfield, Mass. Remember, it’s not Springfield, Illinois. That’s Abe Lincoln.

STUDENT: OK. But tell me about the last one.

SIEGEL: Theory isn’t much. [Paul Anthony] Samuelson teaches about how to make inputs for two points, and when to dribble.

STUDENT: Samuelson teaches drivel?

 

ACT III

(A group of students, griping.)

STUDENT 1 (Francis Michel Bator?): This place is no good. It’s theory, theory, theory all the way. Anyone knows that the way to win at basketball is to practice. Practice makes perfect. Theory makes perfect fools. All you do is study and take exams. “Who was James Naismith? Who was Adam Yea-Smith? When do you chop down the tree?” Bah! I say we ought to study policy. With a two-point lead and three minutes to go, should you freeze the ball or plop in an input for an output of two points?

STUDENT 2 ([Paul Narcyz] Rosenstein-Rodan?): They tell me [Robert Merton] Solow has been converted from theory to policy. He is no longer interested in questions like whether the best set shot is an inverted rectangular parabola, but real issues, like the queuing problem: how many substitutes does a team need to field five men for an hour, with one personal foul every six minutes and four personal fouls per man disqualifying. If you have too many players on the bench you get unemployment. The team needs growth. Maybe you ought to add a man and play six.

STUDENT 3 ([Robert] Evans?): What’s bad is to have to play far away from the Sloan building. Those workshops on top on Walker and over in the Armory are OK, but they are too far away. We need the Ford Foundation to give us a workshop right here.

STUDENT 1: Haven’t you heard? The talk is that the new building to go up in the back lot is a library. But as I see its dimensions unfold- 90 feet by 50 – and transparent backboards and netting and grandstands, I can’t believe it’s a library. It must be a basketball court.

 

ACT IV

(A meeting of the G.E.A.)

RALPH BULL (played by [Robert Lyle] Bishop?): Do any of you fellows have suggestions for speakers besides Cousy, Russell, Jungle Jim Lusketoff, and that 6.8 outstanding economist, [John Kenneth] Galbraith, who can stand with his head coming up through the basket?

STUDENT B: What about Milton Friedman? He is under the five feet which some say is the minimum allowable in a monetary theorist, but he sure is good at the far-fetched shot.

STUDENT B: Why not get Clifford Odets?

RALPH BULL: Clifford Odets? Why him?

STUDENT B: Don’t you remember the famous line in “Awake and Sing”? “My brother Sam joined the Navy. He don’t know from nothin’, that dumb basketball player.” I want to know whether the emphasis is “that dumb basketball player” or “the [sic] dumb basketball player”. Are there any smart basketball players?

 

ACT V

KINDLEBERGER: As chairman of this exam, let me tell you that you have the right to pick the order of your exam. Do you want to start with Theory, or Statistics?

STUDENT (Samuelson?): I think I’ll start by jumping against Fisher, your professorship, sir. Ando’s the smaller, so I’ll take him last when I’m tired.

KINDLEBERGER: All right. (Student and Fisher face each other. Kindleberger blows whistle and throws imaginary ball. Cheers of amazement from faculty.)

FISHER: Very well. I have decided to let you combine Theory and Economic History.

STUDENT: Hey, Ref, your Ph.D.ship, sir, I’m not responsible for History. Isn’t that a foul?

KINDLEBERGER: I didn’t see nuthin’.

FISHER: Consider the population explosion of the last 150 years. Discuss the relative roles of (a) men and (b) women in this affair.

ANDO [Albert Keinosuke] : Good shot. That’s two points for our side.

STUDENT: I don’t know that, your cap-and-gownship, sir, but I know the roles are neither reflexive, symmetric, or transitive.

KINDLEBERGER: (blows whistle) Foul. You used big words in a generals. That’s only permitted the faculty.

FISHER: I’ll give Albert my free throw.

ANDO: (taking the foul shot) Please discuss the role of the nearly decomposable take-off in the application of a priori oligopoly theory to the A&P case.

STUDENT: Hey! You guys are ganging up on me.

ANDO: Well, you outnumber us in class.

STUDENT: (driving hard for basket) It can be set up as a nine-dimensional matrix problem and the latent roots dispensed with. I think the take-off is fine if done along the turnpike, watching out for model changes in passing cars.

ANDO: Fantastic! (Faculty huddle.)

KINDLEBERGER: That was a good answer. We’ve decided to give you an Excellent minus for being a good scorer, but to ask you to leave the Institute for fouling out on personals.

KINDLEBERGER, ANDO, FISHER: Rah, team!

 

ACT VI

DOMAR [Evsey David]: Well, you have the degree wrapped up, and now want a job. Not bad. You got a good grade on the orals, and would have gotten a top grade if you hadn’t thought that Stilt Chamberlain played for the Celtics and failed to distinguish Slippery Sam Jones from Casey Jones. Your thesis was entirely satisfactory, on a good topic: How to Get to the Boston Garden from Madison Square Garden: An Application of the Turnpike Theorem. And you even did languages: basketball communication in the Ivy League, or basketball with a broad A. Now the job. What do you think? Big Ten? Ivy League? Small liberal arts? Girls’ rules like Wellesley or Vassar? Or maybe the real big time: Kentucky, Long Island University, St. Joseph’s in Brooklyn, Notre Dame. L.I.U. is to economics like M.I.T. was to economics.

STUDENT (perhaps [Max Franklin] Millikan?): I don’t now if I’m ready for the Big Time.

DOMAR: What about applying some of your basketballmetrics for the government? They need our graduates. Or for an oil company. Maybe you would like to take a ball and a whistle and go abroad, demonstrating technical assistance to underdeveloped countries. There are jobs like that.

STUDENT: No. I guess I’m fussy. What I’d like is just what all the gang would like, to stay here at Cambridge with Harvard and the Celtics, and to referee like you and [Robert Lyle] Bishop and Samuelson, always blowing off your whistle and shouting foul, going first class to conferences, and shouting foul, foul, foul at the students.

 

Source:  M.I.T. Archives. MIT Department of Economics records, Box 2, Folder “GEA 1961-67”.

Image Source:  Boston Celtics players Tom Heinsohn, Bill Russell, Bob Cousy, Bill Sharman and Frank Ramsey in 1960. “Twelve of the greatest Celtics players of all time”  from Boston.com website (March 18, 2018)

 

Categories
M.I.T. Regulations

M.I.T. No general foreign language requirement in MIT Economics PhD program, 1969

 

While the general foreign language requirement for an economics PhD was officially abolished at M.I.T. in 1969, at least Charles Kindleberger (European Economic History) and Evsey Domar (Communist Economies) were free to require their thesis writers to demonstrate competency in a foreign language as needed for research.

________________

Carbon copy of letter from E. Cary Brown to William F. Bottiglia

May 14, 1969

Professor William F. Bottiglia
Head of Department
Modern Language
14N-207

Dear Bill:

The following statement describes our new language requirement. As you see, we hope that your Department will police it when it is needed.

*   *  *   *   *  *   *   *

“The Department has no general foreign language requirements. When a foreign language is essential for full access to the literature in the field of the student’s major interest (e.g., European Economic History, Communist Economies) or to his thesis research, a language requirement will be imposed by the Department upon the recommendation of the Thesis Superviosr or the Graduate Registration Officer. Such a requirement will be administered by the Department of Foreign Literatures and Linguistics, and can be met by satisfactory course work at M.I.T., at other schools, or by examination.”

Sincerely yours,

E. Cary Brown, Head
Professor of Economics

ECB/mr

Source:  M.I.T. Archives. Department of Economics Records, Box 2, Folder “Grad Curriculum”.

Image Source: Technology Review, February 1914.

Categories
Exam Questions Johns Hopkins

Johns Hopkins. Exams for graduate course on business cycles. Domar, 1951-54

 

Below are three final exams for the Johns Hopkins University graduate course on business cycles taught by Evsey Domar. The examination for 1948-49 has been posted earlier, we see that a few of those questions were recycled below.

_______________

Economics 617
BUSINESS CYCLES

Three hours —January 25, 1951—E.D. Domar

  1. How does the U.S. Department of Commerce treat the following items in the computation of gross national product, national income and consumers disposable income:
    1. Interest on the Federal debt paid to consumers.
    2. Dividends received by American consumers from abroad.
    3. Personal income taxes.
    4. Sales taxes.
    5. Social security payments made by the government to individuals.
    6. Undistributed profits of corporations. If you disagree with the Commerce Department methods, present and justify the methods you would recommend.
  2. Set up a simple model of the Keynesian system including its interest theory and explain its essential differences from the so-called classical system.
  1. 1. Construct a model according to the following conditions:

a) Consumption of a given period is a linear function of the income of the same period.
b) Investment of a given period is a linear function of the difference between incomes of two immediately preceding periods.
c) Income is the sum of consumption, investment and an export balance (constant), all of the same period.

  1. Derive the equation describing the movement of income over time.
  2. Analyze this equation for convergence, divergence and fluctuations and derive the critical values of the parameters.
  3. Make a graph of your results.Give a careful explanation of each step.
  1. Now that we are entering an inflationary period, increased production is suggested as an excellent anti-inflation measure. But larger production means larger incomes which intensify inflation. What then is the actual effect of increased production on inflation?
    Indicate clearly each step in your reasoning.

_______________

ECONOMICS 618
BUSINESS CYCLES

E. D. Domar—Three Hours—May 21, 1952

Answer any four questions. They carry equal weights. Your reasoning is more important than your answers.

I.

“So far as capitalism is concerned we are undoubtedly justified in calling underconsumption a disease of old age.” (Paul Sweezy, The Theory of Capitalist Development,” p. 189.)
Comment.

II.

“Technological progress is alleged to create new investment opportunities by making existing capital assets obsolete. But to the extent that such obsolescence was foreseen, the assets were depreciated over a shorter period and thus gave rise to larger gross savings. Therefore expectedtechnological progress fails to stimulate the economy.”

III.

Hansen emphasizes the positive effect of the growth of population on investment, national income and employment. Yet during the depression many countries suffering from unemployment tried to reduce immigration.
Can you explain this contradiction?

IV.

About 1945 or 1946 when a large loan to Britain was discussed in Washington, the New York Times tried to justify it on the grounds that the British were sure to spend all this money in the United States. On the other hand, the Russians (who also might have asked for a loan) could not be so trusted.
Comment on this and develop your answer into an essay.

V.

Write an essay on any subject related to the course but not covered in your term papers. Take something interesting if possible.

_______________

THE JOHNS HOPKINS UNIVERSITY
E. D. Domar              May 21, 1954

ECONOMICS 617-618
(Business Cycles)

Three Hours

Answer all questions. They carry equal weights.

I.

Present and analyze some (respectable) business cycle theory not discussed in your own term paper.

II.

The following statement appeared in the National City Bank Monthly Letter (Jan. 1944) regarding government spending as a means of raising the level of income and employment:

“Government spending tends to be like a drug, in that it takes larger and larger doses to get results, and all the time debt and taxes get higher and higher.”

Comment. What could be said regarding private investment directed to the same purpose?

III.

“In spite of his claim to the contrary, Keynes did not succeed in proving the possibility of underemployment equilibrium if wages and prices were assumed to be flexible. That a long period of unemployment could persist as a result of wage and price rigidity we had known long before Keynes.”

Comment on this statement and show what effects flexible prices and wages would have on elimination of unemployment (in a depression) and a bottleneck (during inflation). Indicate clearly every step in your analysis. What practical recommendations follow from your discussion?

IV.

The following comment was made by Mr. Ayzenshtadt, a Soviet economist, in 1947:

“Even the greatest admirers of Keynes and of his theory that loan capital is the main propeller of the industrial cycle, do not see anything new in it…Keynes himself thinks that the ‘novelty’ of his system lies in the equilibrium formula of the economic process, in which the independent and dependent variables are arranged as follows:

Independent variables:

1. Propensity to consume
2. Marginal efficiency of capital
3.Rate of interest
4. Liquidity preference.

Dependent variables:

1. Saving
2. Investment
3. Level of employment.”

Comment. Be specific.

Source:  Duke University. David M. Rubenstein Library of Rare Books and Manuscripts. Economists’ Papers Archives. The Evsey D. Domar Papers, Box 16, Folder “Final Examination, Business Cycles”.

Image source: Domar, Evsey D.“” Webpage at the MIT Museum Website.

Categories
Courses Curriculum M.I.T.

M.I.T. Student evaluations of first term core macroeconomics. Domar, 1967-69

 

The economic theory core courses at M.I.T. during the four academic years 1966/67 through 1969/70 consisted of two terms of microeconomic theory (“Economic Analysis”, 14.121 and 14.122) and two terms of macroeconomic theory (“Theory of Income and Employment”, 14.451, and “Economic Growth and Fluctuations”, 14.452). The instructors for the course by academic year were: 

14.121 (Term 1) 14.122 (Term 2) 14.451 (Term 1) 14.452 (Term 2)
1966/67 Bishop Samuelson Eckaus

Solow

1967/68

Bishop Samuelson Domar Solow
1968/69 Bishop Samuelson Domar

Foley

1969/70

Bishop Samuelson Domar

Foley

A retrospective evaluation survey of these four courses was conducted (probably) sometime in late-1970. The original student responses wound up in Evsey Domar’s files and can be found today in his papers in the Economists’ Papers Archive at Duke University.

In other posts we have the responses for Robert Bishop’s Economic Analysis (14.121), Paul Samuelson’s term of Economic Analysis (14.122), and Robert Solow’s/Duncan Foley’s Economic Growth and Fluctuations (14.452).

In this post we’ll look at Evsey Domar’s course, Theory of Income and Employment (14.451),  that covered the topics:

national income,
general aggregative systems,
price flexibility and employment,
theory of interest and demand for money,
consumption and savings,
investment,
multiplier and accelerator,
employment and inflation.

First I provide the information about the course found in the announcement in the MIT course catalogues that essentially remained unchanged for the years from which the evaluations were solicited. The official course staffing and enrollment data that follow the course announcement confirm that Evsey Domar taught 14.122 in the last three years surveyed. We also learn the names of the two instructors who taught the recitation sections for Richard Eckaus and Evsey Domar.

Next I include the cover letter for the questionnaire sent out along with a tabulation of responses to the qualitative questions regarding the amount of economics presumed, the amount of mathematics and the balance of the course among the topics nominally covered.

Finally, and very much worth reading!, the interested visitor will find transcriptions of the written student comments concerning Domar’s course.

____________________

Announcement in the Course Catalogues

14.451T Theory of Income and Employment(A)

[Eckaus]
Prereq.:14.05
Year:G (1) 4-0-8

Examination of principal determinants of aggregate levels of income and employment.

Source: MIT. Catalogue 1966-67: p. 291.

page 219:

“ ‘T’ at the end of a subject number indicates that (1) a change has been made in the content or units of the subject or (2) the number was previously assigned to a different subject.
(A)’ following the name of a subject indicates that it is an approved subject for a graduate degree…
‘G’ is a graduate subject.
The time distribution of the subject, showing in sequence the units allotted to: recitation and lecture; laboratory, design, or field work; and preparation. Each unit represents 15 hours of work. The total unit credit for a subject is obtained by adding together all the units shown. One unit of recitation or lecture credit, and two units of laboratory or design credit, are each equivalent to one semester hour.”

Catalogue 1967-68: Course number drops T; Domar is the instructor, p. 307

Catalogue 1968-69:  Prerequisite for 14.451 changed to 14.06T, p. 312

Catalogue 1969-70:  no change, p. 294.

____________________

Course staffing and enrollments 14.451
First term of 1966-1969

1966: Term I. 3 hours/week. 44 regular students, 2 Listeners.

Professor Eckaus with Instructor J. R. Harris

1967: Term I. 3 hours/week 55 regular students, 4 Listeners.

Professor Domar with Instructor J. R. Harris

1968: Term I.  3 hours/week, 55 regular students, 3 Listeners

Professor Domar with Assistant S. Lewis  (1 hour per week recitation)

1969: Term I. 3 Hours/week. 51 regular students, 2 Listeners.

Professor Domar with Assistant Professor J.R. Harris (1 hour per week recitation)

Source:M.I.T. Archives. Department of Economics Records. Box 3, Folder “Teaching Assignments”

____________________

THEORY QUESTIONNAIRE

There are two problems that the theory sequence must continually face if it is going to be as useful as possible. The first of these is adjusting to the changing background of the incoming students. The second is adjusting to the changing needs of students who will use the theory course as background for other courses and research. This questionnaire is an attempt to gather information of the current state of the theory sequence relative to these two questions. The enclosed forms contain an outline of each of the theory courses and asks three questions.

These pertain to each heading in the course outline:

Does the course assume too much or too little economics background in this area?
Does the course use too much or too little mathematics in this area?
Given the overall constraint of time, is this area gone into too deeply or not deeply enough?

For each of the questions there is room to check too much or too little, no check at all to be given if the course is about right. Please put the year in which you took the theory courses at the top of each page. There is also room in each area for more detailed comment. Use this space to be specific on the changes in the given areas which you feel would be improvements—particularly in answer to question 3. Use the space at the bottom of each page to comment on topics that are not on the list, but should appear in the course; or to make other comments we haven’t thought to ask for.

Please return to 52-380 (Miss Pope) before Tuesday, October 21.

 

[Summary from 20 student responses:
of which 8 from 1967-68; 10 from 1968-69; 2 from 1969-70]

Ec 451:

Economic background Math

Coverage

National Income Too little: 4

Too much: 0

Too little: 1

Too much: 1

Too deep: 10

Not deep enough: 2

General Aggregative systems Too little: 3

Too much: 1

Too little: 2

Too much: 0

Too deep: 1

Not deep enough: 4

Price Flexibility and employment Too little: 2

Too much: 1

Too little: 1

Too much: 0

Too deep: 3

Not deep enough: 4

Theory of interest and demand for money Too little: 2

Too much: 1

Too little: 1

Too much: 0

Too deep: 1

Not deep enough: 7

Consumption and savings Too little: 3

Too much: 0

Too little: 1

Too much: 0

Too deep: 2

Not deep enough: 5

Investment Too little: 2

Too much: 0

Too little: 1

Too much: 0

Too deep: 0

Not deep enough: 9

Multiplier and accelerator Too little: 2

Too much: 0

Too little: 2

Too much: 0

Too deep: 0

Not deep enough: 5

Employment and inflation Too little: 2

Too much: 1

Too little: 1

Too much: 0

Too deep: 0

Not deep enough: 13

 

Note: the responses from Richard Eckaus’ time (first term, 1966-67) have been excluded from this table, so the above are solely for the three years Evsey Domar taught the theory of national income and employment.

 

From the student comments
[each bullet point from a different student]

YEAR TAKEN: 1967-68

  • The Worst Course of the sequence, especially the section’s instructor. Applies to all these points. Tries to cover too much; being an authority in (almost) nothing. Applies to both instructors.
  • I don’t remember 451 very well—it was an awfully unstructured course (+ remains so in my mind), mybe because of the variety and profuseness of the subject matter. Too little guidance from Professor Domar + Harris—i.e., their considered opinion should be given more often.
    National income: Too much on statistics, tho I agree some is needed. That problem in class was a pile of crap—I can’t add anyway.
    General aggregative systems: more tournaments needed.
    Theory of interest and demand for money: more needed, and more guidance from profs.
    Investment: more needed and more guidance from profs.
  • Price flexibility and employment: I thought the section of the course on Patinkin was extremely interesting and well done.
    Consumption and saving: A unified treatment of the competing theories would be preferred to the n-th repetition of Duesenbery, Friedman, Modigliani.
    [for both 451 and 452]: As these courses were taught two years ago there was too little integration of the two terms. Partly this reflects a real gap in macro theory itself; I would like to see an integration of the Patinkin-type of analysis into growth theory.

 

YEAR TAKEN: 1968-69

  • National income: good that this is done, even if not very pleasant at the time
    Price Flexibility and employment: Too much on Patinkin.
    Employment and inflation: More important to cover this Phil curve., monet v. fiscal pol debate etc. than Patinkin
    Perhaps 451 could have assumed more backgrd as it tended to be slow going sometimes. But that’s a minor point. And better that way than to blur over the material too fast. 14.451 exam questions tended to be well-set + testing e.g. the opera + arias.
  • National Income: The index no. prob. was discussed at too great length and too little depth.
    General Aggregative systems/Price flexibility and employment: These two topics were covered fairly well.
    Theory of interest and demand for money: coverage sketchy
    Consumption and savings: very well discussed
    Investment: All I know about investment I learned in other courses—14.452, monetary, econometrics.
    Multiplier and accelerator: The Samuelson multiplier-accelerator article is read in 14.452; all of the items covered in 14.451 under this heading are silly.
    Employment and inflation: no coherent coverage at all.
  • Multiplier and accelerator: Difference equations ought to be specifically covered, with some applications.
  • National Income “+index numbers”: Time should have been more carefully allocated in order to include appropriately the last part of the course.
  • National Income and General aggregative systems: too much, need new, simpler national income.
    Pretty good presentation of money topics.
    No coverage of Investment/Multiplier+Accelerator/employment and inflation at the end.
  • National income: Although this certainly should be covered—too much time is spent on this topic.
    General aggregative systems: Nothing is done in the course on modern macro-static models & e.g.—the Correspondence Principle. The course must assume a complete background in standard macro—because this is hardly covered.
    Much too much time is spent on Patinkin—which could be sued for covering Modern Macro-Static models.
  • Price flexibility and employment: the basics of Keynes should be discussed more.
    Employment and inflation: inflation models of newer sort should be included.
  • don’t want N.I. removed from 451, just reduced!
    [comment for all topics besides national income]: I realize that this is an impossible preference [to have more depth in all the other topics of 451], maybe the answer is another course in macro theory! or less of other things in 452.
  • [For both 451 and 452]: I do not like the Socratic method, especially when applied to solving differential equations. All courses tend to move too slowly at the beginning.
  • National income: It was a mistake to spend so much time on this + none on inflation—change priorities.
    Investment: Treated a little superficially
    Multiplier and accelerator: Use difference equation techniques.
    Employment and inflation: This was not covered at all unfortunately.
    In general 452 was good, 451 seemed weak.

 

Source:  Duke University. David M. Rubenstein Rare Book and Manuscript Library, Economists’ Papers Archive. Evsey D. Domar Papers.Box 16, Folder “Student Evaluations (1 of 2)”.

Image Source: MIT Museum website

Categories
Courses M.I.T.

M.I.T. Student evaluations for core microeconomics course taught by Samuelson, 1970

 

The economic theory core courses at M.I.T. during the four academic years 1966/67 through 1969/70 consisted of two terms of microeconomic theory (“Economic Analysis”, 14.121 and 14.122) and two terms of macroeconomic theory (“Theory of Income and Employment”, 14.451, and “Economic Growth and Fluctuations”, 14.452). The instructors for the course by academic year were: 

14.121 (Term 1) 14.122 (Term 2) 14.451 (Term 1) 14.452 (Term 2)
1966/67 Bishop Samuelson Eckaus

Solow

1967/68

Bishop Samuelson Domar Solow
1968/69 Bishop Samuelson Domar

Foley

1969/70

Bishop Samuelson Domar

Foley

A retrospective evaluation survey of these four courses was conducted (probably) sometime in late-1970. The original student responses wound up in Evsey Domar’s files and can be found today in his papers in the Economists’ Papers Archive at Duke University.

In other posts we have the responses for Robert Bishop’s Economic Analysis (14.121), Evsey Domar’s National Income and Employment (14.451) and Robert Solow’s/Duncan Foley’s Economic Growth and Fluctuations (14.452).

In this post I’ll limit attention to the term in the core taught by Paul Samuelson, namely, course 14.122 that covered the topics of consumer theory, general equilibrium, capital theory and welfare economics.

First I provide the information about the course found in the announcement in the MIT course catalogues that essentially remained unchanged for the years from which the evaluations were solicited. The official course staffing and enrollment data that follow the course announcement confirm that Paul Samuelson taught 14.122 in the four consecutive years surveyed. We also learn the names of the four instructors who taught the recitation sections for Samuelson’s course.

Next I include the cover letter for the questionnaire sent out along with a tabulation of responses to the qualitative questions regarding the amount of economics presumed, the amount of mathematics and the balance of the course among the topics nominally covered.

Finally, and very much worth reading!, the interested visitor will find transcriptions of the written student comments concerning Samuelson’s course. These reports of Samuelson’s teaching from the last half of the 1960s are consistent with my memory from the spring of 1975. The general laments about economic theory seen in some of the evaluations are not unfamiliar to those who have cared to listen to their students over the intervening decades.

____________________

Announcement in the Course Catalogues

14.121T Economic Analysis (A)

[Bishop]
Prereq.: 14.03
Year: G (1) 4-0-8

14.122T Economic Analysis (A)

[Samuelson]
Prereq.: 14.121
Year: G (2) 4-0-8

General theory of equilibrium under competition and monopoly. Theory of consumer choice, of demand, of the firm, of production and distribution, of welfare economics.

Source:  MIT. Catalogue 1966-67, p. 289.

“ ‘T’ at the end of a subject number indicates that (1) a change has been made in the content or units of the subject or (2) the number was previously assigned to a different subject.

‘(A)’ following the name of a subject indicates that it is an approved subject for a graduate degree…

‘G’ is a graduate subject.

The time distribution of the subject, showing in sequence the units allotted to: recitation and lecture; laboratory, design, or field work; and preparation. Each unit represents 15 hours of work. The total unit credit for a subject is obtained by adding together all the units shown. One unit of recitation or lecture credit, and two units of laboratory or design credit, are each equivalent to one semester hour.”
Source:  MIT. Catalogue 1966-67, p. 219.

MIT. Catalogue 1967-68: Same without T, p. 305. 
MIT. Catalogue 1968-69: Prerequisite for 14.121 changed to 14.04T, p. 310.
MIT. Catalogue 1969-70:  p. 293.

____________________

Course staffing and enrollments 14.122
Second term of 1967-1970

1967: Term II. 3 hours/week. 40 regular students, 0 Listeners.

Samuelson with Assistant Professor C. D. MacRae

1968: Term II. 3 hours/week. 53 regular students, 3 Listeners.

Samuelson with Instructor D. Jaffee [2 sections]

1969: Term II.  4 ½ hours/week. 49 regular students, 1 Listener

Samuelson with visiting Assistant Professor H.J.B. Rees.

1970: Term II. 3 Hours/week. 40 regular students, 0 Listeners.

Samuelson with Assistant Professor  R. E. Grieson (1 hour per week recitation)

Source: M.I.T. Archives. Department of Economics Records. Box 3, Folder “Teaching Assignments”

____________________

THEORY QUESTIONNAIRE

There are two problems that the theory sequence must continually face if it is going to be as useful as possible. The first of these is adjusting to the changing background of the incoming students. The second is adjusting to the changing needs of students who will use the theory course as background for other courses and research. This questionnaire is an attempt to gather information of the current state of the theory sequence relative to these two questions. The enclosed forms contain an outline of each of the theory courses and asks three questions.

These pertain to each heading in the course outline:

Does the course assume too much or too little economics background in this area?
Does the course use too much or too little mathematics in this area?
Given the overall constraint of time, is this area gone into too deeply or not deeply enough?

For each of the questions there is room to check too much or too little, no check at all to be given if the course is about right. Please put the year in which you took the theory courses at the top of each page. There is also room in each area for more detailed comment. Use this space to be specific on the changes in the given areas which you feel would be improvements—particularly in answer to question 3. Use the space at the bottom of each page to comment on topics that are not on the list, but should appear in the course; or to make other comments we haven’t thought to ask for.

Please return to 52-380 (Miss Pope) before Tuesday, October 21.

[Summary from all 22 student responses:
of which 2 from 1966-67; 8 from 1967-68; 10 from 1968-69; 2 from 1969-70]

Ec 122:

Economic background Math

Coverage

Consumer theory

Too little: 0

Too much: 1

Too little: 1

Too much: 1

Too deep: 3

Not deep enough: 1

General equilibrium

Too little: 0

Too much: 1

Too little: 2

Too much: 0

Too deep: 0

Not deep enough: 8

Capital theory

Too little: 2

Too much: 2

Too little: 1

Too much: 0

Too deep: 0

Not deep enough: 12

Welfare economics

Too little: 1

Too much: 1

Too little: 0

Too much: 0

Too deep: 0

Not deep enough: 7

 

From the student comments,
Each bullet point from a different student.

YEAR TAKEN: 1967-68

  • Neither of the courses [121/122] give any mention to the modern treatments (esp., set-theoretic approach) of this material.
  • Needs much more [capital theory]
  • For 121 and 122: Both these courses are excellent for covering the technical aspects of price theory—but both fail to provide a “total picture” of what price theory is about”.
  • General equilibrium: some of the new formulations should be discussed.
    Capital theory: less classical, more current theory would be better.
  • OK [for assumed economics background, math, coverage].
    Capital theory: need more and careful lectures—this hard to comprehend
    Welfare economics: good.
  • Math in this part was not too much if it had been presented without assuming we already knew it all—could have had more careful explanation of mathematical concepts used without decreasing the amount or level of math used. [secretary wrote at top of page: not in tabulation—she just gave it to me]
  • For 121 and 122:In general, I thought both terms, despite their widely differing methods, were quite good. I would like to see more problem sets in 122, however, if necessary, just simplified examples of the theorems proved in class. Specifically, there are too few problems in general equil, of 2 person, 2 good sort. Such problems could usefully illustrate gen. equil. and welfare econ. and the differences between the two types of analysis.

 

YEAR TAKEN: 1968-69

  • Consumer theory: would have been better to start with the simplest case rather than with that rather horrific 1st lecture, which was not al all clear.
    Capital theory: coverage was not clear
    Welfare economics: would have liked more.
    GENERAL exam questions in 14.122 re discrimination etc were very interesting + tested absorption of material much more than the standard “regurgitate” question.
  • While the noted professor who offers this course is a student of economic history [history of economics is what is clearly meant] par excellence, gifted with a dashing wit and a marvelous grasp of the anecdotal style, his comparative advantage most certainly lies in economic theory. His students have, no doubt, considered the stage as a possible career, and have universally rejected it in favor of Economics. It logically follow then that in any 90 minute period the teaching of Economics should occupy at least the majority of the time. Theatrics has its place, no doubt, to add flavor and wit to the otherwise Dismal Science, but balance is of the essence. In retrospect, we seem to have covered several major topics during the course of the term. The mind boggles at the thought of what we might have done with an hour and fifteen minutes of economics per period instead of the usual 20 minutes! (A little more care in the preparation of handouts would also have been highly appreciated).
    On a more serious note, I would personal have appreciated a more thorough analysis of the normative branch of Economics. I feel that much more time should have been allotted to Welfare Economics, in particular, to the implications of economic theory to actually policy questions. I don’t believe, as Samuelson implied in his Chomsky “debate”, that normative considerations come only after the scientist has completed his appropriate (positive) tasks. The economist has a very definite social responsibility, to which all the theorizing in the world, taken by itself, contributes not in the least.
    Comment on the Basic Theory (and, in fact, most of the courses taught at M.I.T.) The basic trend that Economics appears to be following, at least at the Ph.D. level, distresses me more and more with each consideration. High powered theory, while undoubtedly a great mental exercise, becomes merely a game when it seeks to find justification solely within itself. As young economists in an increasingly troubled world, we have a distinct obligation and a unique opportunity to aid society. Economics prides itself at its supposed superiority over its sister Social Sciences, yet it is letting its advantages, an in fact its raison d’être, slip away. Our students are far too complacent, and the course material we are taught helps perpetrate this disease. A far greater stress must be place on realism, applications and normative goals. A discipline that exists merely or mostly in professional journals and material that has as its only object the employment of economics professors is an anachronism and a decided mis-allocation of resources.
  • The topics are well chosen and worthwhile and the readings are valuable. But Prof. Samuelson should spend more time organizing his lectures and guiding his students through these unfamiliar fields and less time telling his fascinating, charming, and irrelevant stories. The lectures are the weakest part of the course.
  • Samuelson wastes the opportunity. Too many anecdotes, not enough time on the actual material. Needs to be much more systematic and organized.
  • Capital theory and welfare economics, particulary the former should have been gone over in more detail-excessive speed obscures the fact that the overall coverage may be good and satisfactorily deep.
  • General equilibrium: The 2-factor, 2-good example would be helpful here as an illustration.
    Capital theory: The treatment in this area seemed superficial. 122 would have been more enjoyable if I had had a prior course in the mathematical theory of optimizing with constraints.
  • 121-122-451-452 All four courses well taught: main difficulty with the theory sequence is the poor integration of the four parts. Less isolation, more cross-references would help.
  • [on math] Hicks reading is too mathematical or too old (Hicks…).
    [on coverage] reasonably good allocation [across topics]
    Welfare economics. Repetitive. Need typed notes. The notes are good should be typed.
    [In red marker:] Samuelson does not appear to want to teach 122.
    Find some new victim.

 

Source:  Duke University. David M. Rubenstein Rare Book and Manuscript Library, Economists’ Papers Archive. Evsey D. Domar Papers.Box 16, Folder “Student Evaluations (1 of 2)”.

Image Source:  Samuelson Memorial Information Page/Photos from Memorial Service.  Accessed via the Internet Archive Wayback Machine.

 

Categories
Exam Questions Johns Hopkins

Johns Hopkins. Mid-year and End-year final exams for business cycles. Domar, 1948-49

 

Copies of the examinations for Evsey Domar’s business cycles course at Johns Hopkins University offered during the 1948-49 academic year can be found in his papers at the Economists’ Papers Archives at Duke University but also in the archived collection of economics exams in the departmental papers at the Johns Hopkins archive. While Domar was fairly reliable in keeping copies of his course outlines and exams, I have yet to discover a course outline for any year. Perhaps he lent his sole copy to a colleague once?

Three sets of examination questions for 1951, 1952, and 1954 are also posted.

____________________

Course Announcement

Business Cycles 617-618. Associate Professor Domar. Two hours weekly through the year.

Statistical descriptions of fluctuations in economic activities and a systematic survey of past and present cycle theory.

 

Source: Catalogue Number of The College of Arts and Sciences; The School of Engineering; The School of Business in Johns Hopkins University Circular. New Series 1948, Number 3. Whole Number 579 (March, 1948) p. 85.

____________________

THE JOHNS HOPKINS UNIVERSITY
FINAL EXAMINATION

Economics 617
Dr. Domar

Wednesday, January 26, 1949—9 a.m. Three hours

ANSWER ALL QUESTIONS. THEY CARRY EQUAL WEIGHTS. I AM MOST INTERESTED IN YOUR REASONING.

I.

In the last days of the OPA, it was emphatically asserted by various quarters that the best cure against inflation lay in increased production. Assume than an increase in output was actually possible. Would not increased production, however, result in larger money incomes and thus produce an inflationary effect, or at least counteract the deflationary effect of the increase in output?
Analyse this problem. The quality and depth of your analysis will count more than its quantity.

 

II.

Mr. Ayzenshtadt, whose paper was read in class, has this to say about Keynes’ system:

“Even the greatest admirers of Keynes and of this theory that loan capital is the main propeller of the industrial cycle, do not see anything new in it….Keynes himself thinks that the ‘novelty’ of his system lies in the equilibrium formula of the economic process, in which the independent and dependent variables are arranged as follows:

Independent variables

  1. Propensity to consume
  2. Marginal efficiency of capital
  3. Rate of interest
  4. Liquidity preference

Dependent variables

  1. Saving
  2. Investment
  3. Level of employment.”

Comment. Be specific.

 

III.

“In spite of his claims to the contrary, Keynes did not succeed in proving the possibility of underemployment equilibrium if wages and prices were assumed to be flexible. That a long period of unemployment could persist as a result of wage and price rigidity we had known long before Keynes.”

Comment on this statement and show what effects would flexible prices and wages have on elimination of unemployment (in a depression) and stabilization of the price level (in an inflation). Indicate clearly every step in your analysis. What practical recommendations follow from your discussion?

 

IV.

Write for thirty – forty minutes on any subject covered in the course which is of interest to you, but is not included in the preceding questions and not studied in your term paper. Make sure you have something worthwhile to say.

*  * *  *  *

The Johns Hopkins University
Final Examination

Economics 618
Dr. E. D. Domar

May 25, 1949. Three hours

Answer all questions. They carry equal weight.

I.

The following statement appeared in the National City Bank Monthly Letter (Jan. 1944) regarding government spending as a means of raising the level of income and employment:

“Government spending tends to be like a drug, in that it takes larger and larger doses to get result, and all the time debt and taxes get higher and higher.”

            Can a somewhat similar statement be made regarding private investment as an instrument for achieving and maintaining a high level of employment? Discuss the problem thoroughly.

 

II.

Examine the monetary equations (Nos. 3.10, 3.11, 3.12 in Klein’s Model III. (You should have his paper with you.)

[Klein, Lawrence R. “The Use of Econometric Models as a Guide to Economic Policy.” Econometrica 15, no. 2 (1947): 111-51. ]

  1. Give a thorough analysis of their meaning and structure.
  2. Explain the function which they perform or are supposed to perform in the system taken as a whole.
  3. State your criticism of them and present your positive suggestions.

 

III.

A Congressional Committee is holding hearing to determine (a) the causes of depressions and, (b) the methods for their elimination. Mr. Hayek and Mr. Marx are testifying. (You may use Mr. Paul Sweezy instead of Mr. Marx if you don’t want to get involved with ghosts).

Present:

  1. A brief statement of each witness’ views on points (a) and (b).
  2. Your criticism and evaluation of these statemtns.
  3. Your own statements on points (a) and (b).

Make sure that your position is well taken because both the witnesses and the members of the Committee (not to say anything about your instructor) can attack you on any point. Be precise and specific.

 

IV.

Evaluate critically the present day business cycles theory and research. Present your positive suggestions for their improvement. In what direction should the study of business cycles, in your opinion, develop? Be specific.

 

Source:     Duke University. David M. Rubinstein Rare Book and Manuscript Library, Economists’ Papers Archive. Evsey Domar papers, Box 16, Folder “Final Exams: Johns Hopkins, Stanford, U of Michigan”.

Image Source: College yearbook portrait of Evsey [Domashevitsky] Domar from the 1939 UCLA yearbook.

Categories
Amherst Chicago Economists Harvard M.I.T. Placement

Chicago. Zvi Griliches asking Frank Fisher for junior appointment leads, 1961

 

In a 1961 memo Zvi Griliches reported to his Chicago colleagues some scouting results regarding a possible junior appointment in economics. He spoke econometrician-to-econometrician with his colleague Frank Fisher at M.I.T. about the most interesting graduate students in the Cambridge area on the job market that year. Four names were mentioned, two unsurprising enough were the names of economists “unable” to be drawn from the gravitational pull of Cambridge. 

Griliches ended his memo with the remark “This year Domar happens to be MIT’s ‘placement officer’ and this is likely to put us at some competitive disadvantage.” Does this mean that Griliches thought the monopsonist Evsey Domar would deliberately discriminate against the University of Chicago?

_______________

Four graduate students discussed by Zvi Griliches and Frank Fisher

Beals, Ralph E. Dept. of Econs. Amherst College, Amherst, MA 01002. Birth Yr: 1936.  Degrees: B.S., U. of Kentucky, 1958; M.A., Northwestern U., 1959; Ph.D., Mass. Institute of Technol., 1970. Prin. Cur. Position: Clarence Francis Prof. of Econs., Amherst Coll., 1966.  Concurrent/Past Positions: Assoc., Harvard Institute for Int’l. Develop., 1973.  Research: Int’l. trade, commercial policy & industrialization in Indonesia.

[According to the Prabook website: Ralph E. Beals was Assistant professor economics, Amherst (Massachusetts) College, 1962-1963; associate professor, Amherst (Massachusetts) College, 1966-1971. ]

Hohenberg, Paul M. RPI, Dept of Econ, Troy, NY 12180. Birth Yr: 1933.  Degrees: B.Ch.E., Cornell U., 1956; M.A., Tufts U., 1959; Ph.D., Mass. Institute of Technol., 1963. Prin. Cur. Position: Prof. of Econs., Rensselaer Poly. Institute, 1977.  Concurrent/Past Positions: Vis. Assoc. Prof., Sir George Williams U., Montreal, 1972-74; Assoc. Prof., Cornell U., 1968-73.  Research: Urbanization & econ. change in Europe and U.S.

Marglin, Stephen A.  Birth Yr: 1938.  Degrees: A.B., Harvard U., 1959; Ph.D., Harvard U., 1965. Prin. Cur. Position: Prof. of Econs., Harvard U.

Temin, Peter. Mass Inst of Tech, Dept of Econ, Cambridge, MA 02139. Birth Yr: 1937.  Degrees: B.A., Swarthmore Coll., 1959; Ph.D., Mass. Institute of Technol., 1964. Prin. Cur. Position: Prof. of Econs., Mass. Institute of Technol., 1970.  Concurrent/Past Positions: Assoc. Prof., Mass. Institute of Technol., 1967-70; Asst. Prof., Mass. Institute of Technol., 1965-67. ResearchEcon. history; telecommunications policy.

 

Source:  Biographical Listing of Members. The American Economic Review, Vol. 83, No. 6 (Dec., 1993).

_______________

Memo on possible appointments written by Zvi Griliches

November 8, 1961

[To:] A. Rees
[From:] Z. Griliches
[Re:] The possible appointments.

I had a long telephone conversation with Frank Fisher last week about “whom we should look at.” It is his opinion that the single best young man coming up now in the Cambridge area is:

Stephen A. Marglin—He is a mathematical theorist, with several papers to his credit. He has spent a year at Cambridge, England and is currently in his second year of a three year Junior Fellowship at Harvard. I had already invited him to give a talk to the workshop and he will be here on January 16 to talk on “The Social Rate of Discount and the Opportunity Costs of Public Investment.” Frank thinks that we would have a very hard time getting him, in particular for next year, but that he is clearly the best.

The best current MIT student that will be coming to the market is, in Fisher’s opinion:

Ralph Beals—who is a third year graduate student specializing in the fields of monetary policy and econometrics. He has been working with Solow and Albert Ando and his interests in the monetary area have appartently been stimulated by Solow’s and Ando’s involvement in the Monetary Commission stuff.

In addition, Fisher mentioned that there are also two ver good “economic historian types” finishing there this year:

Peter Pemin[sic, “Temin”]—who is working with Gerschenkron at Harvard, and
Paul Hohenberg—who is working withKindelberger on the sources of the econonmic development of France in the 19thcentury.

This year Domar happens to be MIT’s “placement officer” and this is likely to put us at some competitive disadvantage.

cc:       H. Johnson, M. Friedman, T. Schultz✓, G. Stigler, W. Wallis.

Source:  University of Chicago Archives. Department of Economics Records, Box 42, Folder 3.

Image Source:  Zvi Griliches from the University of Chicago Photographic Archive, apf1-06565, Special Collections Research Center, University of Chicago Library.

 

Categories
Columbia Economists

Columbia. Appointment of Marcus Fleming as Visiting Professor, Spring 1951

 

I have transcribed the following paper-trail regarding the appointment of Marcus Fleming for a one term visiting Professor appointment because of the biographical information of this important economist included in the letter requesting formal approval from the provost of Columbia University as well as its providing an example of the minimal paperwork apparently required for a visiting position in 1950 compared to what is required in most universities at the present time.

________________

COMMITTEE ON INSTRUCTION
FACULTY OF POLITICAL SCIENCE

MINUTES OF MEETING: October 3, 1950

Present: Professors A.R. Burns, Goodrich, Malone, Peffer, Strong
Absent: Professor Abel
Present by Invitation: Professor Lazarsfeld

[…]

Approval of new appointments

Economics

  1. Marcus Fleming, recent Deputy Director of the British Cabinet Secretariat, as Visiting Professor of Economics (European Institute), for the Spring Session at a salary of $4,500 plus a travelling allowance. (The hope of the Department is to extend this appointment during the period for which funds for the European Institute are at present provided.
  2. Evsey Domar, Associate Professor of Economics at The Johns Hopkins University, as Visiting Associate Professor of Economics 146 while Professor Bergson in on part-time leave.

[…]

Source:  Columbia University Archives. Minutes of the Faculty of Political Science, 1950-1962.

________________

Letter from Department Head Professor James W. Angell
to Vice-President and Provost Dr. Grayson L. Kirk

October 10, 1950

Dr. Grayson L. Kirk,
Vice President and Provost
of Columbia University,
Low Memorial Library.

Dear Dr. Kirk:

I enclose herewith a Nomination for Appointment, requesting the appointment of John Marcus Fleming to the position of Visiting Professor of Economics (European Institute.) I believe this appointment has already been acted upon favorably by the Committee of Instruction of the Faculty of Political Science.

Mr. Fleming, who is married and has several children, is a little past forty. He received the degree of Master of Arts, with Honours in History (1932), and in Economics (1934), at Edinburgh University. He studied Economics further at the London School of Economics, 1934-35. He then became a member of the Secretariat of the League of Nations in Geneva, 1935-38, and in the latter part of that period was a member of the Economic Intelligence Service. He spent 1938-39 in the United States as a Rockefeller Fellowship. Since 1939 he has held a series of posts I the service of the British government, combined with extensive teaching at the University College in London. Beginning with the latter part of the war, and down to this past summer, he has been Deputy Director of the Economic Section in the British Cabinet Secretariat. He has served as a British representative to the Organization for European Cooperation in Paris, and to the United Nations at Lake Success. His written work includes a large study of American business cycles, prepared for the League of Nations just before the war, as a working document, but not formally published, and some half dozen important articles in leading professional journals, on problems of economic theory and international trade.

Sincerely yours,
[signed]
James W. Angell
Executive Officer
Department of Economics

[Penciled note in margin: OK/GK]

Source:   Columbia University Archives. Central Files 1890-, Box 409, Folder “Angell, James W. 7/1950-6/1953”

________________

Carbon copy of response of Dean John A. Krout to Professor James W. Angell

16 October 1950

Professor James W. Angell
Executive Officer
Department of Economics
Fayerweather

Dear Professor Angell:

I have your letter to Provost Kirk about the nomination for appointment of John Marcus Fleming to the position of Visiting Professor of Economics (European Institute) during the period from February 5, 1951 to June 30, 1951. Since this nomination has the approval of the Committee on Instruction of the Faculty of Political Science, I am sending through the appropriate authorization.

Cordially yours,

John A. Krout
Dean

mp
cc: Miss Mullen

Source:   Columbia University Archives. Central Files 1890-, Box 409, Folder “Angell, James W. 7/1950-6/1953”

Image Source:  Marcus Fleming (1911-1976) page at Policonomics.com

Categories
Exam Questions Fields M.I.T.

M.I.T. General exam questions, fiscal economics, 1963

 

The following general exam in fiscal economics was found in Evsey Domar’s papers at Duke University’s Economists’ Papers Archive. Two students apparently took this examination and were graded by Domar:  Michael Repplier Dohan (MIT Ph.D., 1969) and Silva (unable to determine first name).

_________________

September 23, 1963

GENERAL EXAMINATION IN FISCAL ECONOMICS
THREE HOURS

Please answer THREE QUESTIONS, ONE from each part. Use a separate examination book for each question.

Part I.

  1. Write an essay on the subject of “The Effect of Built-In Stabilizers on the Growth and Fluctuations of the American Economy.”
    Explain what they are and how they work.
  2. State the economic objectives which the American Federal Government, in your opinion, should pursue at the present time and explain how well (or badly) the details of the proposed tax reduction; indicate, however, what kind of reductions you have in mind).

 

Part II.

  1. Explain as fully as you can the economic effects of a, say, 50 per cent income tax imposed on (a) corporations, and (b) all businesses. Indicate the positions taken by the authorities in the field, your own position, and methods of testing them.
  2. Abba Lerner has suggested that the best tax would be a kind of a poll tax imposed on each individual not in relation to his actual income but to his potential income (what he could earn) as estimated by the tax authorities.
    Leaving the practical aspects of this proposal aside, explain the following:

    1. What objectives was Lerner trying to accomplish by means of this unusual tax?
    2. What does this proposal tell you about Lerner’s general economic philosophy?
    3. What defects in our existing (federal) tax structure was Lerner trying to eliminate by this proposal?
    4. How would you deal with the defects indicated in (c)? Be specific.

 

Part III.

  1. Explain as fully as you can the objectives to be pursued and the problems likely to be encountered by recurrent deficit financing (an excess of expenditures over receipts) if practiced by the following organizations:
    1. The American Federal Government
    2. The national government of India or of some other underdeveloped country
    3. An American state (or local) government
    4. American business as a whole
    5. An American business corporation.
  2. Amoz Morag, an Israeli economist, once said that our whole theory of public finance, having been developed mostly in England and in the United States, is based on certain economic philosophy natural to these countries but not to the underdeveloped ones. For the latter, a very different approach to public finance is required, frequently leading to conclusions and methods diametrically opposed to the usually accepted ones.
    Comment fully.

 

 

Source:  Duke University. David M. Rubenstein Rare Book and Manuscript Library. Economists’ Papers Archives. Evsey Domar Papers, Box 16, Folder “Ph.D. examinations, Fiscal Economics”.

Image Source:  Evsey Domar from the MIT Museum website.